Parallel Trade and its Ambiguous Effects on Global Welfare
Abstract
The regulation of parallel trade is a fiercely debated issue in the global trading system. This paper investigates the welfare effects of parallel trade freedom for different levels of trade costs and market size. It is found that parallel trade freedom has a positive effect on global welfare if countries are sufficiently heterogeneous in terms of market size and trade costs are sufficiently low. Contrary to intuition, this result even holds in a situation where parallel trade freedom implies the closure of the smaller market. If, however, countries are virtually homogenous in terms of market size, parallel trade freedom may be detrimental to global welfare for specific levels of trade costs.
1. Introduction
The regulation of parallel trade is a fiercely debated issue in the global trading system. At the heart of this debate is the ambiguous nature of the welfare effects of parallel trade, an aspect which has been noted by Ganslandt and Maskus (2004), Maskus and Chen (2004), and Valletti and Szymanski (2006). A compromise reached under World Trade Organization (WTO) law permits countries to freely decide whether to allow or ban parallel trade.1 Advocates of strong patent rights for pharmaceuticals support a global policy banning parallel trade. Danzon (1998) argued that if parallel trade of pharmaceuticals were permitted, profits in the pharmaceutical industry would decrease, thereby reducing incentives to invest in research and development (R&D) for new drugs. Grossman and Lai (2008) opposed this argument. Nevertheless, as pointed out by Maskus (2001), policymakers in many developing countries support an open regime of parallel trade and place a greater emphasis on the affordability of pharmaceuticals than on promoting R&D abroad.
Maskus and Ganslandt (2002) put forward that parallel trade freedom may increase prices in low-income countries and result in smaller markets not being served. We will show that this assertion is correct for specific combinations of parallel trade costs and heterogeneity of countries in terms of market size. However, we will also show that in this case parallel trade freedom still exerts a positive effect on global welfare even though small markets remain unserved. This conclusion contrasts with previous work on the welfare effects of parallel trade by Jelovac and Bordoy (2005) and Malueg and Schwartz (1994).2
There are three main strands of literature on the determinants of parallel trade.3 First, Maskus (2000) and Maskus and Chen (2004) suggested that multinational companies build markets through exclusive territorial dealership rights in order to vertically control the operations of their licensees. They may, however, find it difficult to enforce private contractual provisions prohibiting sales outside the authorized distribution chain so that parallel trade occurs. Our study of parallel trade is closely related to this strand of literature. Second, Brekke et al. (2009) and Ganslandt and Maskus (2004) suggested that in certain industries such as the pharmaceutical industry national governments intervene in private markets by regulating prices. As this results in international price differences, there is a potential for arbitrage between markets as put forward by Grossman and Lai (2008) and Richardson (2002). A third determinant of parallel trade, as suggested by Maskus (2000), is the incentive of parallel importing firms to free ride on investments in marketing as well as on the before- and after-sales services of official licensees and authorized distributors.
2. Simple Model of Parallel Trade
We consider a model with two countries, denoted by subscript j = A,B, and two firms. In country A there is a monopolistic manufacturer m. In country B there is a single authorized independent firm r that is responsible for the distribution and retail of the manufacturer's product. We assume that efficient international distribution of the product requires the manufacturer to build a market in B through exclusive territorial dealership rights. Suppose that the exclusive distributor in B has already established costly distribution channels. The demand in A is qA = γa − bpA, and the demand in B is qB = a−bpB, with γ > 1. Let γ measure the heterogeneity of the two countries in terms of markets size. Let Π denote the profit of the manufacturer and π the profit of the distributor, respectively. For simplicity, we assume that the marginal costs of production are equal to zero in both countries. The exclusive distributor sells to consumers in B at first, but may also engage in parallel trade from B to A. Arbitrage by individual consumers between B and A is legally prohibited. The marginal costs of engaging in parallel trade are denoted by t. They include, following Berka (2009), Li and Maskus (2006), and Maskus and Chen (2004), parallel-trade specific distribution and advertising costs as a result of re-packaging and re-labeling as well as import duties on parallel trade. We assume that the parallel import product is a perfect substitute for the product sold by the original producer in A. We analyze a situation in which the manufacturer is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade as a benchmark.
Double Marginalization without Parallel Trade







Double Marginalization with Parallel Trade
Suppose that the manufacturer cannot prohibit or at least contractually limit parallel trade. In the first stage, the manufacturer chooses the wholesale price ,
, at which he sells the product to the distributor in B. In the second stage, the distributor chooses the retail price pB, pB ∈ [0, ∞), in B. In the third stage, the manufacturer m and the exclusive distributor r simultaneously choose the prices at which they sell the product in A in a Bertrand model of duopoly, e.g.
,
, and
,
, respectively.
Proposition 1. Parallel trade does not occur in any sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium in a double marginalization game with Bertrand price competition in the last stage.




















Note that (
) is equal to the monopoly price (profit-maximizing wholesale price) in a double marginalization game in which parallel trade is prohibited. Intuitively, if the two countries are virtually homogeneous (γ → 1) and the parallel trade costs are so high that t > th, the distributor will not be willing to engage in parallel trade.
3. Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom on Profits



In both situations, with and without parallel trade, equilibrium prices and quantities in countries A and B are identical if t > th. The threshold for low trade costs is denoted by tl. The distributor will only be willing to sell the product in B as long as (
). From this follows:
. Intuitively, if trade costs are very low, t < tl, potential competition from parallel trade is so fierce that the manufacturer has to charge such a high wholesale price in B in order to deter parallel trade that the distribution of the good in B becomes unprofitable.
To summarize, we consider three scenarios. First, parallel trade costs are so high, t > th, that parallel trade is not a worthwhile activity for the distributor and thus a non-credible threat. Parallel trade freedom then does not have any impact on profits, consumer surplus as well as national and global welfare. Second, the manufacturer strategically sets prices in order to deter parallel trade if tl ≤ t ≤ th. However, the wholesale price will be sufficiently low so that the distribution of the product in B is still a worthwhile activity. Third, the manufacturer will charge such a high wholesale price in B in order to deter parallel trade that the market in B ends up not being served if t < tl.
Effect of Parallel Trade Freedom on the Profit of the Manufacturer
For intermediate and low trade costs, the equilibrium profits of the manufacturer are , and
, respectively, if parallel trade is permitted. If, however, the manufacturer is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade, his profit does not depend on the level of trade costs and is given by Π** = (a2/8b)(2γ2 + 1).
Proposition 2. The threat of parallel trade leads to lower profits for the manufacturer (i) if trade costs are intermediate, or (ii) if trade costs are low.
The proof is straightforward since (i) and (ii)
. Intuitively, parallel trade is not a credible threat and does not erode the manufacturer's ability to discriminate prices if t > th. If trade costs are intermediate or low, however, parallel trade is a credible threat and the manufacturer sets prices strategically as a deterrent. According to Lutz (2004), the threat of parallel trade then erodes the manufacturer's ability to discriminate prices and thus reduces his profit as opposed to a situation where he is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade. An important point in favor of banning parallel trade is the following. Under the assumption that an investment in R&D leads with certainty to the development of a new product, the maximum amount the manufacturer is willing to invest ex ante is his expected profit. A ban on parallel trade then leads to higher R&D incentives since the profit of the manufacturer under a ban on parallel trade is higher than that under parallel trade freedom as Valletti and Szymanski (2006) have argued. Hence, if the unique social objective were to spur R&D for new products by protecting the manufacturer, our model suggests that the manufacturer should be awarded the right to prevent parallel trade.
Effect of Parallel Trade Freedom on the Profit of the Distributor
If the manufacturer is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade, or if it is permitted but trade costs are high, the profit of the distributor is given by . If trade costs are intermediate and parallel trade is permitted, the distributor will make a profit according to
. Parallel trade freedom is detrimental to the distributor in this case as
at its unique maximum tl. The manufacturer will charge a higher wholesale price in country B—as compared with the wholesale price under a ban on parallel trade—in order to deter parallel trade. Hence, the distributor will sell less at a higher price resulting in a lower profit under parallel trade freedom. Finally,
if t < tl.
4. Effect of Parallel Trade Freedom on Global Welfare


We derive the welfare effects of parallel trade freedom by subtracting global welfare if the manufacturer has the right to prevent parallel trade from global welfare under parallel trade freedom. Recall, however, that even if parallel trade were permitted, the (non-credible) threat of parallel trade would not have any impact on global welfare if t > th.
Welfare Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom for Intermediate Trade Costs
Proposition 3. Parallel trade freedom increases global welfare if trade costs are intermediate and (i) γ ≥ 5/2 or (ii)
.

Note that ΔWi is a quadratic function of t. Note also that ΔWi = 0 at th = (a/2b)(γ − 1). Hence, in order to show that ΔWi ≥ 0, it is sufficient to show that ΔWi is a monotonically decreasing function of t for tl ≤ t ≤ th. From follows
. As
is the unique maximum, ΔWi decreases in t for any
. Taking into account that ΔWi = 0 at th = (a/2b)(γ − 1), it follows that ΔWi > 0 for
. We analyze for which values of γ
. It is straightforward to see that
if γ ≥ 5/2. Furthermore, ΔWi monotonically decreases in t for tl ≤ t ≤ th. Hence, taking into account that ΔWi = 0 at th, ΔWi ≥ 0 if γ ≥ 5/2.
(ii) If γ < 5/2, we cannot apply the same logic as in the previous case as tl = (a/2b)(γ − 5/2) would be negative. Since t is non-negative, we set tl = 0 in this case. For γ < 5/2, ΔWi has its unique maximum at , which is positive as γ < 5/2. Hence, the question arises as to whether ΔWi is positive or negative at tl. If we can show that ΔWi is positive at t = 0, this would imply that ΔWi is also positive for tl ≤ t ≤ th, taking into account that ΔWi = 0 at th. By setting t = 0 in (9) we obtain ΔWi = (a2/72b)(4γ2 − 11γ + 7). Note that ΔWi ≥ 0 if γ ≥ 7/4. Consequently, if γ ≥ 7/4, ΔWi is positive between zero and th. Thus, ΔWi ≥ 0 if 7/4 ≤ γ < 5/2. □
Intuitively, parallel trade freedom harms both the manufacturer as well as the distributor. Parallel trade freedom is also detrimental to consumers in country B because it leads to a higher local retail price and a lower quantity sold. Hence, consumers in country A are the only beneficiaries from parallel trade freedom. As long as γ is sufficiently large, 7/4 ≤ γ, the positive effect of parallel trade freedom on consumers in A ceteris paribus more than outweighs the sum of its negative effects on the manufacturer, the distributor, and consumers in B.
In contrast, Numerical Example 1 illustrates that the following proposition holds.
Proposition 4. Parallel trade freedom can exhibit negative welfare properties if trade costs are intermediate and γ is sufficiently low [1 < γ < 7/4].
Recall that ΔWi = 0 at th = (a/2b)(γ − 1). By looking at (9), it becomes apparent that ΔWi has another null at t = (a/2b)(7/2 − 2γ) > 0 as γ < 7/4.
Numerical Example 1. We set a = 100, b = 1/2 and γ = 13/8.
Figure 1 shows that ΔWi = 0 at t = 25 and at t = th = 62.5. Furthermore, ΔWi has its unique maximum at . Also, tl = 0. We can see from Figure 1 that ΔWi < 0 ∀t ∈ (0, 25), which suggests that Proposition 4 holds. If countries A and B are virtually homogeneous, 1 < γ < 7/4, consumers in A will benefit less from parallel trade freedom. In this case, the effect of parallel trade freedom on global welfare will be negative if trade costs are intermediate.

Welfare Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom (a = 100, b = 1/2, and γ = 13/8)
Welfare Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom for Low Trade Costs
Proposition 5. Parallel trade freedom increases global welfare if trade costs are low and γ is sufficiently high, γ > 5/2, even though the smaller market remains unserved.

As we can see, ΔWl is a quadratic function of t. Recall that γ must be greater than 5/2 as t > 0. For smaller values of the parameter γ, we would automatically end up in one of the other scenarios mentioned above. By differentiating (10) we obtain .
is the unique maximum as
. Furthermore,
. By setting t = 0 in (10), we obtain ΔWl = (a2/288b)(20γ2 − 16γ − 67). We can see that ΔWl > 0 at t = 0 if γ > 5/2. By setting t = tl = (a/2b)(γ − 5/2) in (10), it follows that ΔWl = (a2/8b)(γ − 2). ΔWl > 0 as γ > 5/2. Consequently, taking into account that ΔWl is a quadratic function of t,
, ΔWl > 0 at t = 0, and ΔWl > 0 at tl, it is straightforward to see that ΔWl > 0 if tl > t and
. □
Contrary to intuition, parallel trade freedom still has a positive effect on global welfare in this case even though the market in B remains unserved. If γ is sufficiently high, the positive effect of parallel trade freedom on consumers in A ceteris paribus more than outweighs its negative effects associated with lower profits for the manufacturer and the closure of the market in B.
5. Conclusion
Our two-country model of parallel trade based on the work of Maskus and Chen (2004) suggests that the threat of parallel trade can limit the monopolistic manufacturer's scope for price discrimination and thus increase retail-market competition. While this finding is in line with the prior literature on parallel trade, such as Ganslandt and Maskus (2004) and Malueg and Schwartz (1994), we find that the manufacturer's strategic pricing to avert parallel trade depends on the level of heterogeneity of countries in terms of market size and on the level of parallel trade costs. If parallel trade costs are high, potential competition from parallel trade does not arise, and the manufacturer will always charge the monopoly price in the domestic market. If, however, parallel trade costs are low, potential competition from parallel trade arises, and the manufacturer advantageously sets prices in the domestic and foreign market in order to avert parallel trade. In an empirical, policy-oriented article, Maskus and Ganslandt (2002) have put forward that parallel trade may increase prices in low-income countries and lead to the closure of smaller markets. Our analysis confirms this assertion under the condition of low trade costs and sufficient heterogeneity of market size in both countries. Because of the threat of severe competition from parallel trade, the manufacturer sets a prohibitively high wholesale price in the foreign market resulting in unprofitable product distribution abroad. Consequently, it would be desirable for policymakers in the foreign country to discourage parallel trade and to encourage price discrimination in order to open the otherwise unserved market. Nevertheless, we also show that even in this case global welfare is positively affected through parallel trade freedom. It is in this respect that we believe our analysis is different from existing works such as Maskus and Chen (2004), Valletti (2006), and Valletti and Szymanski (2006).
As to the general welfare properties of parallel trade freedom, it increases global welfare if countries are sufficiently heterogeneous in terms of market size. Yet, for intermediate trade costs and virtually homogeneous countries, parallel trade freedom can have negative welfare properties. In this case, the negative effect on the manufacturer, the distributor, as well as on consumers in the foreign country more than outweighs the positive effect of parallel trade freedom on domestic consumers. Considering these ambiguous welfare effects, we suggest that neither parallel trade freedom nor a ban, but instead a rule of reason is justified from an economic perspective.