Generalized Equilibrium Problems Related to Ky Fan Inequalities
Abstract
We study a generalized equilibrium problem by using a nonsymmetric extension of Ky Fan’s inequality. As an application, we present a fixed point type algorithm inspired by a model from Tada and Takahashi (2007).
1. Introduction
In this paper, we study a generalized equilibrium problem which is connected with some results from [1, 2]. More precisely, by using a nonsymmetric extension of Ky Fan’s inequality, we solve a special class of equilibrium problems, which can be fitted into the field of minimax inequalities. By using such type of generalized equilibrium problems we consider a fixed point type algorithm based on two iterative sequences. Such type of problems have been extensively studied [1–4]. Other interesting results concerning equilibrium problems can be found in [5, 6].
Several methods for solving systems of equilibrium problems in Hilbert spaces are studied in [3]. The proposed methods include proximal-like block-iterative algorithms for general systems, as well as regularization and splitting algorithms for single equilibrium problems.
On the other hand, the study of such inequalities, fixed point of nonlinear mappings, and their approximation algorithms can be successfully used in order to solve some equilibrium problems. In [1] two iterative algorithms for a generalized Ky Fan inequality and a fixed point problem of asymptotically strict pseudocontractions are studied. A strong convergence theorem is also obtained based on the hybrid projection method in Hilbert spaces. Moreover, in [2, 7, 8], weak and strong convergence theorems of finding a common element of the set of fixed points of a nonexpansive mapping and the set of solutions of the equilibrium problem have been studied.
Let us consider a function f : C × C → ℝ, where C is a nonempty, compact, and convex subset of a Hilbert space ℋ.
Let g : C → C be one to one continuous functions, F : C × C → ℝ and r > 0.
We remark that if we choose x = g−1(z) we obtain the classical equilibrium problem (EP). The aim of the paper is to solve the generalized equilibrium problem (3) under the suitable conditions imposed to the function F and to study some related problems.
Note that many classes of problems can be fitted in the class of equilibrium problems. In the following, we present such classes of problems which can be solved as an equilibrium problem.
In order to formulate the saddle point problem as an equivalent equilibrium problem, we define C = C1 × C2 and f((x1, x2), (y1, y2)) = ϕ(y1, x2) − ϕ(x1, y2). The function f is also monotone, that is, f((x1, x2), (y1, y2)) + f((y1, y2), (x1, x2)) = 0.
We present now an application to economics, given by a Nash equilibrium problem. Suppose that we have a finite set ℐ of N players. Let Ci be the finite set of pure strategies of player i ∈ I. We define C = ∏i∈I Ci. For all i ∈ I, let fi : Ci → ℝ be the loss function of player i. For arbitrary x = (x1, …, xn) ∈ C, we define .
It can be shown that is a Nash equilibrium point, more precisely a solution of (11), if and only if it is a solution of the equilibrium problem (EP), where f : C × C → ℝ is given by .
Let us consider now a fixed point problem. If T : C → C is a map, then is a fixed point of T if and only if is a solution of the equilibrium problem (EP), where f(x, y) = 〈x − Tx, y − x〉.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we use some minimax theory elements in order to obtain a nonsymmetric form of Ky Fan’s inequality for the case of quasiconvex functions. In Section 3, we solve the generalized equilibrium problem (GEP) by using the extension of Ky Fan inequality and we discuss some related problems and applications.
2. A Nonsymmetric Extension of Ky Fan’s Inequality
In this section, we present a nonsymmetric extension of Ky Fan’s inequality for the case of quasi-convex functions. In a similar way, Ky Fan’s inequality has been extended in the context of metric spaces with global nonpositive curvature. More details and results on this topic can be found in [9–11].
Definition 1. We say that a function g : E → F is quasi-convex if
Firstly, we present the classical Knaster-Kuratowski-Mazurkiewicz (KKM) theorem, which will be used later.
Theorem 2 (KKM). Assume that for every point x belonging to a nonempty set X ⊂ E there exists a closed subset M(x) ⊂ X. Suppose that the following property:
We prove now a nonsymmetric extension of Ky Fan’s inequality by using a continuous and onto function.
Theorem 3. Let D, F be two nonempty, compact, and convex subsets of E and let g be a continuous onto function g : F → D. Let f : D × F → ℝ be a function which is upper semicontinuous in the first variable and quasiconvex in the second variable. Then, one has
Notice that Theorem 3 extends the classical Ky Fan inequality. More exactly, taking D = F and g(z) = z for all z ∈ F in Theorem 3 we obtain (13).
Proof. Consider the family of sets
We will show that we can apply the results from KKM’s theorem. First of all, we remark that g(y) ∈ M(g(y)) ⊂ D, for y ∈ F.
Let A = {g(y1), g(y2)} be a subset of D. For more elements of D the proof is similar. We need to show that
Indeed, if the contrary is true, then for a λ ∈ (0,1) we have
From the continuity of g, we infer the existence of an element yλ ∈ D such that
Let h : [0,1] → F be a continuous function such that
Hence, h(0) and h(1) are of contrary signs and we deduce the existence of an α0 ∈ [0,1] such that h(α0) = 0.
We have
Thus, we obtain a contradiction. Hence, we can apply KKM’s theorem and we have that ∩y∈FM(g(y)) ≠ ∅. It follows that there exists x0 ∈ D such that for every y ∈ F we have
With similar arguments, we can prove the following theorem in the case of quasiconcavity.
Theorem 4. Let D, F be two nonempty, compact, and convex subsets of E and let g : D → F be a continuous onto function. Let f : D × F → ℝ be a quasi-concave function in the first variable and lower semicontinuous in the second variable. Then, one has
An important application of the above theorems is the existence of an g-equilibrium which generalizes the existence of the well-known concept of Nash equilibrium. See [10].
Theorem 5. Let C = C1 × C2 × ⋯×Cn, where Ci, i = 1, …, n are nonempty, compact, and convex subsets of E, let g = (g1, g2, …, gn) : C → C be a continuous onto function, and let fi : C → C be a function which is lower semicontinuous in the second variable and xi → (fi)(y1, …, g(xi), …, yn) is quasiconcave for every i = 1, …, n. Then, there exists an y ∈ C such that
3. Main Results
In this section, we use the above nonsymmetric extension of Ky Fan’s inequality in order to solve the generalized equilibrium problem (GEP). In the following, we present the strategy of solving the generalized equilibrium problem (GEP) which will be used later to present a fixed point type algorithm.
We pass now to the problem of proving the existence of an element z ∈ C which solves (30).
Lemma 6. Let g : C → C be a continuous bijective function and let F : C × C → ℝ be a quasiconvex function in the second variable and upper semicontinuous in the first variable which verifies
Remark 7. Here, the novelty consists of the fact that we can solve (30) by imposing weaker conditions than those from [1–3]. More precisely, the symmetric condition f(z, z) = 0 is replaced with a nonsymmetric one, given by F(z, g(z)) ≥ 0, for each z ∈ C.
Proof. Let us consider Fg(z, y) = F(z, y)+(1/r)(y − g−1(z), g−1(z) − x). Since the function F is quasiconvex in the second variable (as the sum of a quasi-convex function and a linear function) and upper semicontinuous in the first variable, then by applying Theorem 3 we obtain
In fact, (32) says the fact that there exists z ∈ C such that
Hence, we have an element z ∈ C which solves (30) and the proof is finished.
Note that Lemma 6 will be used to study two iterative sequences which converge to a common element of the set attached to a nonexpansive mapping and the set of solutions of an equilibrium problem in a Hilbert space. The ideas are based on several results from [2], when the conditions imposed are symmetric f(z, z) = 0. By assuming weaker conditions we prove that similar results hold.
Definition 8. Let C be a nonempty, closed, and convex subset of a real Hilbert space ℋ and let g : C → C be a continuous and bijective function. We say that a bifunction F : C × C → ℝ verifies the g-equilibrium conditions if
- (a)
F(g(x), x) = 0, for all x ∈ C;
- (b)
F(g(x), y) + F(g(y), x) ≤ 0, for all x, y ∈ C;
- (c)
limsupt↓0F(tz + (1 − t)x, y) ≤ f(x, y), for all x, y, z ∈ C;
- (d)
F(x, ·) is convex and lower semicontinuous for each x ∈ C.
Definition 9. The generalized resolvent of a bifunction F : C × C → ℝ is the set-valued operator JF : ℋ → 2C defined by
Lemma 10. Suppose that F : C × C → ℝ satisfies the g-equilibrium conditions and let
- (i)
domJF = ℋ;
- (ii)
JF is single-valued and firmly nonexpansive; that is, for any x, y ∈ ℋ
(37) - (iii)
for each x ∈ C g(x) ∈ JF(x) is equivalent with the fact that g(x) ∈ SF;
- (iv)
SF is closed and convex.
Proof. (i) By using Lemma 6 we deduce that for every x ∈ ℋ there exists a point z ∈ C such that
(ii) Let (x, x′) ∈ ℋ × ℋ and let z ∈ JF(x), z′ ∈ JF(x′). It follows that
Therefore, by using condition (b) from Definition 8 we have that
In particular, for x = x′, we obtain z = z′, which implies that JF is single valued. Moreover, from (41) we derive that JF is firmly nonexpansive.
(iii) Let us consider x ∈ C. Then g(x) ∈ JF(x) means exactly that
(iv) It follows from (ii), (iii), and the g-equilibrium conditions.
We are now in position to present an extension of Theorem 3.1 from [2] in the case of our weaker generalized g-equilibrium conditions.
Theorem 11. Let C be a nonempty closed convex subset of a Hilbert space ℋ. Let F : C × C → ℝ a bifunction satisfying the generalized g-equilibrium conditions and let S : C → ℋ be a nonexpansive mapping such that
Proof. The strategy is based on the model from the proof of Theorem 3.1 in [2]. For the convenience of the reader we present here only the main steps of the proof.
First step consists in proving the fact that the sequence (xn) n≥1 is well defined. It is easy to see that Cn∩Dn is a closed convex subset of ℋ for each n ∈ ℕ. Let g(v) ∈ Fg(S)∩EP(f), by using that we have that
Moreover, we obtain that
Hence, v ∈ Cn and Fg(S)∩EP(f) ⊂ Cn, for every n ∈ ℕ. Moreover, by induction we can show that F(S)∩EP(f) ⊂ Cn∩Dn, for each n ∈ ℕ. We deduce that (xn) n≥1 is well defined, and hence by Lemma 6 the sequence (un) n≥1 is also well defined.
Let us denote by . Since we have
Since and xn+1 ∈ Dn, we have
The rest of the proof becomes more similar with the one from Theorem 3.1 in [2], and we recall here only the main steps.
In the first step, it is proved that
By using Lemma 10 we have that
Later on, the fact that limn→∞∥xn − v + g(v) − un∥ = 0 is proved. Next, we obtain limn→∞∥un − Sun∥ = 0 and w ∈ Fg(S)∩EP(f).
Finally, we conclude that
Conflict of Interests
The author declares that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.
Acknowledgment
This work was supported by a Grant of the Romanian National Authority for Scientific Research, CNCS-UEFISCDI, Project no. PN-II-RU-TE-2011-3-0223.