Volume 33, Issue 4 pp. 327-342
Research Article
Full Access

Dynamic Dependence Between Liquidity and the S&P 500 Index Futures-Cash Basis

Donald Lien

Donald Lien

Donald Lien is at College of Business, University of Texas at San Antonio, Texas

Search for more papers by this author
Gerui Lim

Gerui Lim

Gerui Lim is at School of Banking and Finance, University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia

Search for more papers by this author
Li Yang

Corresponding Author

Li Yang

Li Yang is at School of Banking and Finance, University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia

Correspondence author, School of Banking & Finance, Australian School of Business, The University of New South Wales, Sydney, NSW 2052, Australia. Tel: +61 2 9385 7936, Fax: +61 2 9385 6347, e-mail: [email protected]Search for more papers by this author
Chunyang Zhou

Chunyang Zhou

Chunyang Zhou is at Antai College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, China

Search for more papers by this author
First published: 27 April 2012
Citations: 15

The authors are grateful for helpful comments and suggestions by an anonymous referee, the editor, Bob Webb, and participants at the 2009 FMA Meetings. Li Yang gratefully acknowledges the financial support of the Australian School of Business at University of New South Wales. Chunyang Zhou would like to acknowledge NSFC funding support (no. 71001071).

Abstract

Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam (2007) investigate the linear relationship between stock market liquidity and index futures-cash basis. We extend their work and examine nonlinear relationship between the two variables of interests, in particular, tail dependence. We find that the tail dependence is asymmetric and varies significantly over times. The lower tail dependence between changes in (il) liquidity measured by bid–ask spread of S&P 500 index and changes in absolute value of S&P 500 index futures-cash basis is almost zero and the upper tail dependence is positive and significantly different from zero. The results suggest that an increase in liquidity is not always associated with a decrease in basis. However, a reduction in liquidity is significantly associated with an increase in basis. At the extreme situation, the link between changes in basis and changes in liquidity can break down. Arbitrage profits cannot be realized and hedging becomes less effective. © 2012 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 33:327-342, 2013

1. INTRODUCTION

Liquidity is a broad term in finance, which refers to an asset's ability to be easily converted through the course of buying or selling in large quantities without causing significant price movements and with minimum loss of value. Numerous studies on liquidity have shed light on the importance of this economic fundamental. Amihud and Mendelson (1986) show that stock returns are positively related to the bid–ask spread (i.e., one of liquidity measures). Pastor and Stambaugh (2004) find that stocks with higher sensitivities to fluctuations in liquidity (i.e., liquidity risk) earn higher returns on average. Chordia, Roll, and Subrahmanyam (2002) find that liquidity plummets significantly in down markets.

More recently, liquidity is linked to arbitrage activities in derivatives markets, which cause market prices to converge to the fair values. For example, Deville and Riva (2010) examine the determinants of the time it takes for an index options market to return to the no-arbitrage value in the presence of put–call parity deviations. They show that liquidity-linked variables are associated with a faster reversion of arbitrage profits after controlling for conventional impediments to arbitrage. Roll, Schwartz, and Subrahmanyam (2000) argue that deviations from the no-arbitrage condition, particularly the zero futures-cash basis induced by the cost-of-carry relation, should be related to market liquidity, because illiquidity impedes arbitrage activities. At the same time, a large futures-cash basis may trigger arbitrage trades and thereby affect liquidity. They test the conjecture by investigating the joint dynamic structure of aggregate NYSE market liquidity and the NYSE composite index futures-cash basis with a vector autoregression (VAR) model and find a two-way Granger causality between liquidity and basis.

However, a VAR model would not be able to capture the causality between liquidity and the futures-cash basis under extreme conditions, which is very important for hedgers in the futures markets. As suggested by Chordia et al. (2002), liquidity changes more significantly in down markets than in up markets. The asymmetric responses of liquidity to the direction of the market movement imply that the interdependence between liquidity and the futures-cash basis in down markets may differ from that in up markets. This calls for an alternative approach in order to incorporate any nonlinear dependence between basis and liquidity.

In this study, we employ a copula modeling approach to examine the dynamic and asymmetric dependence between liquidity and the futures-cash basis of S&P 500 index. The copula approach enables us to identify the dependence structures and to capture the potential nonlinear relation between the basis and liquidity. Copula theory was first introduced in Sklar (1959). The capabilities of copula models to capture the dependence structure between variables led to growing interest from both practitioners and academic researchers in recent years. In short, copulas are multivariate distributions that can be decomposed into the marginal density function of each variable and a component known as the copula density, which contains all information of the dependence structure. This property offers the flexibility to model the dependence structure of related variables independently from their marginal distributions, highlighting the advantage of the copula theory over standard classical methods.

Using bid–ask spread of the S&P 500 index as a proxy measure for market (il)liquidity, we model the dynamic dependence between changes in the S&P 500 index futures-cash basis and changes in (il)liquidity through the copula modeling approach. As expected, we find that the linear dependence coefficient between the two variables varies through time, ranging from −0.0719 to 0.1050. Contrast to Roll et al. (2000), a large increase in liquidity is not always associated with a large reduction in the deviation from the zero futures-cash basis. Further analysis shows that the upper tail dependence is significantly different from the lower tail dependence, that is, an asymmetric dependence. The upper tail dependence is significantly positive whereas the lower tail dependence is always close to zero. Thus, as market liquidity decreases, the absolute basis increases. The dependence structure between the two variables may break down. On the other hand, as market liquidity increases, the absolute basis does not necessarily reduce. In these situations, arbitragers incur a great uncertainty when attempting to reap the risk-free profits, because the deviation from the no-arbitrage condition is persistent causing a delay in the convergence. Hedging becomes less effective. Consequently, the time varying and asymmetric dependence structure documented in this study provides more information for market participants.

The remainder of the study is organized as follows. In Section 2., we briefly discuss the copula approach to model the dependence between two variables and different copula models we adopt to specify the dynamic relationship between changes in the basis and changes in (il)liquidity. Marginal models for changes in the basis and changes in (il)liquidity are described in Section 3.. A summary of the findings is presented in Section 4.. The conclusion is given in Section 5..

2. MODELING DYNAMIC DEPENDENCE BETWEEN CHANGES IN BASIS AND CHANGES IN MARKET (IL)LIQUIDITY

We first provide a brief introduction of the copula theory. The main references can be found in Joe (2003) and Nelson (2003). A copula is a multivariate distribution expressed as a function of standard uniform (0, 1) marginals. More specifically, a copula is a function urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0001, where urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0002 and satisfy the following three conditions:
  1. For all urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0003, if urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0004, then urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0005;
  2. For urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0006 urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0007, urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0008;
  3. For all urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0009, urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0010-->.

Theorem 1.Let F be the distribution function of k random variables, urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0011, with corresponding marginal distributions (cumulative density function) urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0012, respectively. There exists a copula function C such that

urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0013(1)
If the marginals urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0014, are continuous, then C is unique.

The theorem says a copula links the joint distribution function to the underlying univariate marginal distributions. Define urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0015 as the quasi-inverse of urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0016, such that urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0017. Upon taking the partial derivatives of Equation1 with respect to each variable and noting urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0018, we have the multivariate density as follows:
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0019(2)
where
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0020
and
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0021
Given Equation 2, we are able to decompose the joint density of variables into their univariate densities, urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0022 and a copula density, urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0023. Any dependence structure between the variables is then embedded in the copula density. Equation 2 is a useful result as it allows the univariate dynamic structure to be separated from the dependence structure between the random variables. It also implies that one could more flexibly model the univariate distributions and link them with a copula function that best describes the dependence structures of the random variables. Thus, more flexible multivariate distributions could be easily introduced.

We consider the following two copula functions in this study: (i) the normal copula and (ii) the symmetrized Joe-Clayton (SJC) copula. The normal copula measures the linear dependence between two variables and imposes a symmetric dependence structure, whereas the SJC specification allows for the asymmetric dependence in either direction and measures the tail dependence. In addition, it nests symmetric dependence as a special case. Thus, the normal copula may be considered as a benchmark.

The density of the normal copula is simply the bivariate normal density function
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0024(3)
where urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0025, urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0026 and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0027 is the inverse of the standard normal cumulative distribution function (CDF). For the normal copula, ρ is the only parameter of the normal copula and measures the linear correlation between the two random variables. Implementing the above model allows us to examine the linear dependence between the two random variables, and because the function is parameterized through the correlation parameter, it is rather easier to interpret. However, it is important to note that the correlation parameter does not represent the linear dependence when the underlying variables are not normally distributed.
Equation 3 assumes that the correlation parameter is constant over time. Alternatively, time variation in the correlation parameter can be incorporated to capture the dynamic dependence between the two variables as new information arrives (see, e.g., Dias & Embrechts, 2001; Patton, 2007). We follow Dias and Embrechts (2001) and specify the evolution of the correlation parameter as follows:
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0028(4)
where
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0029
is the Fisher transformation. The autoregressive process in urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0030 captures possible persistence in the correlation parameter, while the average of the past ten lags of urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0031 incorporates possible variation in the dependence pattern into the correlation parameter.
The second copula function employed in this study is the “symmetrized” Joe-Clayton (SJC) copula that is a modification of the “BB7” copula of Joe (2003) by Patton (2007). The “BB7” copula function is given by
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0032(5)
where urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0033, and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0034 measure upper and lower tail dependences, respectively. To elaborate, it is the probability of observing a large (small) value for one variable given a large (small) value for the other variable. The drawback of the “BB7” copula is that the asymmetry behavior in the tail dependence is always enforced even when the tail dependence is de facto symmetric. The SJC copula corrects for this possible bias with the following modification:
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0035(6)
where urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0036 is the “BB7” copula defined as Equation 5. The SJC copula is only a slight modification of the original Joe-Clayton copula, but by construction it is symmetric when the upper and lower tail dependencies are the same, that is, urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0037.
Similarly to the case for the normal copula model, we also allow for time variation in the tail dependence to capture the dynamics of the dependence between the two variables. The evolution is specified as follows:
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0038(7)
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0039(8)
where
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0040
is the inverse of the logistic transformation.

3. MARGINAL DISTRIBUTIONS OF CHANGES IN BASIS AND CHANGES IN LIQUIDITY

To model the joint dependence of two random variables using the copula method, one has to start with the marginal distribution of each variable. We are interested in the dependence structure between changes in the basis and changes in the spot market liquidity. We first discuss the model specification of changes in the basis and then discuss proxies for market liquidity and model specification of changes in liquidity. Previously, Chen, Duan, and Hung (1999) specify the basis change by a normal-GARCH model. We adopt the following skewed Student's t-GARCH specification instead:
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0041(9)
where about urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0042 is the futures-cash basis at time t and defined as a percentage term. urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0043 and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0044 are the futures and spot prices, respectively. Roll et al. (2000) link time variation in the basis to stock market liquidity. urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0045 in the mean equation, that is, Equation 6, denotes the change in the basis from time urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0046 to time t, and it follows an ARMA(1,1) process. Equations 7 and 8 assume that the error term follows a GARCH(1,1) process. urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0047 is assumed to follow a skewed Student's t-distribution proposed by Hansen (1997) with zero mean and unit variance. The distribution is defined as follows:
math image
where urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0049 is the degree of freedom, and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0050 is the skewness parameter. urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0051, and c are three constants, given by
math image
When urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0053, it nests to Student's t-distribution.

As mentioned above, Chen et al. (1999) assume that the standardized residuals urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0054 follow a normal distribution. However, it is well known that financial variables, especially when measured over short time intervals (i.e., daily or weekly), are characterized by nonnormality. In particular, return series exhibit fat tails (excess kurtosis) and are often skewed (Jondeau & Rockinger, 2003; Patton, 2006). Bollerslev (1987) combines the GARCH model with standard Student's t-density to account for fat tails. In addition, asymmetric GARCH model incorporates the leverage effects to generate asymmetric conditional densities. However, this model often fails to adequately describe the asymmetry effect in equity returns (see, e.g., Patton, 2006, 2007). We assume that urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0055 follows the Hansen's (1997) skewed Student's t-distribution for its analytical tractability and its past success in fitting changes in the basis. For comparison purpose, we also fit the data with the standard normal distribution despite that, given the non-normality of spot and futures returns, we expect changes in the basis to be nonnormal as well. Based upon distribution adequacy tests, the standard normal is found to be misspecified in terms of uniformity of the probability integral transform whereas skewed Student's t-distribution is deemed adequate.

We follow Roll et al. (2000) and use bid–ask spread as a measure of (il)liquidity. More specifically, we use a scaled bid–ask spread as an illiquidity indicator, defined as
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0056(10)
We construct aggregate scaled bid–ask spread of S&P 500 index on a daily basis for the period January 2002 to December 2008. We follow several rules that have been commonly used in the literature to clean the raw data. First, to be included for calculating the aggregate scaled bid–ask spread, a stock is required to be present at the beginning and at the end of the year in both the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) and the intraday databases. Second, for each stock, quotes established before the market opens or after the market closes are discarded from intraday data. Third, negative values for bid–ask spreads, transaction prices, and quoted depth are discarded from the intraday data. Fourth, the quoted bid–ask spreads larger than five dollars and the scaled bid–ask spreads larger than 0.4 are also discarded from the intraday data. For each stock, the scaled bid–ask spreads are averaged across the day to obtain the daily stock illiquidity measures. The daily scaled bid–ask spreads are then averaged across stocks to obtain the daily aggregate scaled bid–ask spreads, that is, aggregate illiquidiaty measure of S&P 500 index.
The model specification for changes in illiquidity is given byw
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0057(11)
where urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0058 is the scaled bid–ask spread at time t and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0059 is the change in the scaled bid–ask spread from time urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0060 to time t. The conditional variance of changes in the spread follows a GARCH(1, 1) process.

4. DATA AND ESTIMATION RESULTS

We collect the data on spot and futures prices of the S&P 500 index from Datastream. The sample period covers from January 1, 2002 to December 31, 2008. The futures contracts are cash settled in March, June, September, and December. To generate a continuous futures price series from the traded contracts, we first use the nearest to maturity contract and then switch to the next nearest to maturity contracts during the delivery month. In the literature, some studies choose to rollover the contract in the first day of the delivery month (e.g., Bessembinder, 1992; Roon, Nijman, & Veld, 2007), a few days before the expiration of current contract, or at expiration day (e.g., MacKinlay & Ramaswamy, 1994; Roll et al., 2000). There is no single rule of when the contract should be switched. In this study, we use two different switching rules: (i) switching the contract five working days (i.e., one week) prior to the expiration of the contract and (ii) switching the contract ten working days (i.e., two weeks) prior to the expiration of the contract. The results with both (i) and (ii) switching rules are similar. Thus, we only report the results based on the five working-day switching rule. The results based on the ten working-day switching rule are available upon request.

Summary statistics of changes in the basis and changes in the scaled bid–ask spread are provided in Table I. Nonnormality is evident from sample skewness and kurtosis. Moreover, the Jarque–Bera test rejects normality at the 1% level of significance for both variables. The ARCH Lagrange multiplier (ARCH LM) tests indicate that significant ARCH effects prevail in the data. The correlation between changes in the basis and changes in the scaled bid–ask spread is positive, suggesting that the higher stock market liquidity, the smaller the deviations of the futures-cash basis from zero.

Table I. Summary Statistics
Changes in Basis Changes in Spread
Mean 0.0007 0.0000
Standard deviation 0.2015 0.0032
Skewness 0.3178 −0.2691
Kurtosis 9.9959 53.2256
Jarque–Bera 0.0010 0.0010
Ljung–Box Q 0.0000 0.0000
ARCH LM statistic 0.0000 0.0000
Correlation coefficient 0.0716
  • Note. The null hypothesis under the Jarque–Bera test assumes normality with test statistic follows a χ2(2)-distribution. The Ljung–Box Q test and the ARCH LM test of Engle (1982) is conducted with ten lags. For Jarque-Bera test, Ljung-Box Q test, and the ARCH test, the numbers reported are the corresponding p-values.

4.1. Dynamics of Changes in the Basis and Changes in the Bid–ask Spread

In this section, we provide the empirical results on the dynamics of changes in the basis and bid–ask spread. In columns 2–3 in Table II, we display the parameter estimates and standard errors for the marginal model of changes in the basis, that is, Equations 5. urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0061 is negative and significantly different from zero at the 10% level, and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0062 is negative but significantly different from zero at the 1% level. Given the estimated coefficients of urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0063 and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0064, we can calculate the first-order autocorrelation of urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0065 for an ARMA(1,1) process as
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0066(12)
The first-order autocorrelation of urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0067 is about −0.4865, implying that changes in the basis is reduced by a proportional amount of the previous changes in the basis. The result suggests a mean reversion in changes in the basis, which is consistent with the findings by Miller, Muthuswamy, and Whaley (1999) and Garrett and Taylor (1994). Estimation results for the conditional variance indicate that strong GARCH effects prevail with the sum of estimated coefficients (urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0068) being very close to one.

In columns 4–5 in Table II, we present the parameter estimates and standard errors for the marginal model of changes in the bid–ask spread, given in Equations 14–17. We find that urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0069 is positive and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0070 is negative, both of which are significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level. The first-order autocorrelation of urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0071 calculated using the above formula is about −0.3383, implying that the spread change is reduced by a proportional amount of the previous spread change. Estimation results for the conditional variance indicate strong GARCH effects.

Table II. Parameter Estimates for Changes in Basis and Changes in Spread
Changes in Basis Changes in Spread
Coefficient Standard Error Coefficient Standard Error
Mean equation
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0072,0 −0.0009 0.0008 0.0000 0.0000
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0073,1 urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0074 0.0288 0.1961*** 0.0432
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0075,2 urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0076 0.0190 urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0077 0.0333
Variance equation
ωi 0.0015*** 0.0003 0.0000*** 0.000
αi 0.1851*** 0.0310 0.2040*** 0.0325
urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0078 0.7862*** 0.0259 0.7960*** 0.0219
Distribution parameters
νi 4.3951*** 0.4319 3.7936*** 0.3514
λi 0.3635*** 0.0317 0.1680*** 0.0337
  • Note. The asterisks, *, and *** represent the 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels, respectively. Note that urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0079or Q.

If a distribution is correctly specified for an underlying variable, the probability integral transform of the variable should be an independently and identically distributed uniform random variable with a range [0,1]. This property provides a test for distribution adequacy. To proceed, we first test whether the standardized residuals are serially correlated using the LM test conducted by regressing the four central moments of the probability integral transform on its own 20 lags. We then test if the probability integral transform of the standardized residuals are uniformly distributed using the Kolmogorov–Smirnov (KS) test statistics. The p-values of the test results for changes in the basis and changes in the bid–ask spreads are reported in the second and third columns of Table III, respectively. It is shown that serial independence and uniformity of PITs cannot be rejected at the 10% significance level for both marginal models.

Table III. Specification Test
Changes in Basis Changes in Spread
First moment LM test 0.4361 0.3392
Second moment LM test 0.9820 0.9995
Third moment LM test 1.0000 1.0000
Fourth moment LM test 1.0000 1.0000
KS test 0.1534 0.6746
  • Note. The LM test is carried out by regressing urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0080 on its own 20 lags for k = 1,2,3,4, where urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0081 represents the standardized residuals. The test statistic is (urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0082 20)R2 , where N is the sample size and R2 is the explained sum of squares from the regressions. The KS test refers to the Kolmogorov–Smirnov The null hypothesis is that the standardized residuals of changes in the basis or spread follow skewed Student's t-distribution with the estimated degree of freedom and skewness parameter.

4.2. Dynamic Dependence Between Changes in the Basis and Changes in the Bid–ask Spread

In Table IV, we present the parameter estimates from the copula models between changes in the basis and changes in the bid–ask spread. The correlation estimate from the constant normal copula model is 0.0066 and statistically insignificantly different from zero. The lower and upper tail dependence estimates from the constant SJC copula are very close to zero, of which the lower tail dependence is statistically insignificant, but the upper tail dependence is statistically significant at the 1% significance level.

Table IV. Parameter Estimates from Copula Models Between Changes in the Basis and Changes in Spread
Coefficient Standard Error
Constant normal copula
ρ 0.0066 0.0240
Copula likelihood 0.0999
Constant SJC copula
τL 0.0000 0.0000
τU 0.0000*** 0.0000
Copula likelihood 0.0883
Time-varying normal copula
ωp 0.0022 0.0072
αp 0.8870*** 0.2209
βp 0.0187 0.0270
Copula likelihood 0.5335
Time-varying SJC copula
ωL 1.2185 43.9169
αL 0.9948*** 0.2274
βL 0.8106 96.1327
ωU 0.5176 0.9968
αU 0.9982*** 0.0024
βU 3.3625 1.6669
Copula likelihood 2.7673
  • Note. The asterisks, *, **, and *** represent the 10%, 5%, and 1% significance levels, respectively.

Under the time-varying normal copula, the autoregressive term urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0083 is estimated to be 0.8870, different from zero at the 1% significance level, and the average past dependence term urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0084 is estimated to be 0.0187, insignificantly different from zero. Figure 1 displays conditional correlation between changes in the basis and changes in the bid–ask spread based on the time-varying normal copula. The value fluctuates mildly around its unconditional value 0.0066. Thus, an increase in the S&P 500 index liquidity is not always associated with a reduction in the basis as suggested in Roll et al. (2000).

Details are in the caption following the image
Time-varying correlation from normal copula.

Under the time-varying SJC copula, the two autoregressive terms urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0085 and urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0086 are estimated to be 0.9948 and 0.9982, respectively, and they are significantly different from zero at the 1% significance level. The two average past dependence terms are estimated to be 0.8102 and 1.6669, respectively, however they are both insignificantly different from zero. Figure 2 displays the time-varying upper tail dependences from the SJC copula model. The lower tail dependences are very close to zero over time, which suggests that a large increase in liquidity is not always associated with a large reduction in basis. The upper tail dependences vary through time. Especially during the financial crisis, there are huge variations in the upper tail dependences. Thus, an asymmetric dependence structure prevails. A positive upper tail dependence suggests that when the absolute basis becomes larger, the bid–ask spread becomes larger as well. In this situation, the deviation of the futures-cash basis from zero may be strongly persistent as there is a great uncertainty for arbitragers to enter the market to take the arbitrage positions.

Details are in the caption following the image
Time-varying upper tail dependences from SJC copula.

5. CONCLUSION

This study investigates the joint dynamics between changes in the S&P 500 futures-cash basis and changes in liquidity of S&P 500 index using a copula modeling approach. Copula theory differentiates from the classical method by allowing one to model the dynamics of the individual variables separately from their dependence structure.

The main results documented in this study are (1) the dependence between changes in the basis and changes in liquidity varies through time, and (2) the tail dependence is asymmetric with significant positive upper tail dependence and zero lower tail dependence. The results suggest that the deviation of the futures-cash basis from zero may be strongly persistent, which discourages arbitragers from entering into the market to exploit arbitrage opportunities. Meanwhile, hedging becomes more costly and less effective.

  • 1 Note that Dias and Embrechts (2001) use one lag whereas we use ten lags, which fits the data well in our study.
  • 2 There are several alternative versions of skewed Student's t-distributions, see, for example, Jones and Faddy (1991) and Azzalini and Capitanio (2003). Hansen's version is more analytically tractable than others.
  • 3 The probability integral transformation (PIT) transforms a set of dependent variables into a set of U(0, 1) variables.
  • 4 We also use the scaled effective bid–ask spreads as the illiquidity measure, which is defined as
    urn:x-wiley:02707314:fut21554:equation:fut21554-math-0087
    and the results are quite similar.
  • 5 There are two types of futures contracts written on S&P 500 index: full size and E-mini size. Our study is based on full-size futures contracts. The trading volume for the full-size contracts have been shrinking over time. There is a downward trend since the beginning of the sample period. The daily average trading volume of nearest to maturity contracts is around 40,000 contracts between 2004 and 2005, whereas the daily average trading volume is about 30,000 contracts between 2006 and the first half of 2007. In 2008, the trading volume is much volatile than the previous years.
    • The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.