[Retracted] Traffic Equilibrium Problems with Cross-Boundary Traffic: A Tradable Credit Approach
Abstract
This study studies the tradable credit scheme design problem considering a mixture of local traffic and cross-boundary traffic. The local traffic refers to the travel demand generated by local residents with O-D pairs inside the network, while the cross-boundary traffic is the traffic with either origin or destination or both be outside the network. As the local authority aims to maximize its local social welfare, it determines the quantity of cross-boundary trips by evaluating the revenue of the cross-boundary traffic. Two credit charging schemes are investigated, i.e., a spatially differentiated credit scheme and an anonymous tradable credit scheme. In the first scheme, due to the different charging prices and the selfishness of the local authority, the travel credits are freely tradable within the local travellers only. The cross-boundary travellers have to buy travel credits from the local authority. In the second scheme, the tradable credit scheme is anonymous. The local authority determines the link-specific number of credits to be charged for using that link, while the travel credits are distributed to local travellers only but are allowed for free trading among both local and cross-boundary travellers. Two standard multi-class traffic equilibrium problems are established with side constraints and a credit restriction constraint. The equilibrium link flow patterns under these credit schemes are then demonstrated with local elastic demand. In both tradable credit schemes, the credit price in the trading market is unique under the equilibrium condition.
1. Introduction
Traffic congestion has caused severe negative effects on productivity, environment, and sustainability of almost all large cities worldwide. Vehicles contribute a major part of the air pollutants in the urban areas, which are apparently higher under congested conditions than under free-flowing traffic conditions. Several traffic management schemes have been proposed to alleviate traffic congestion and emissions, including the market-based approaches (e.g., road pricing and tradable travel permit/credit scheme) and traffic flow control approaches (e.g., signal control and ramp metering). The market-based approaches, as contributed mainly by economists, are demonstrated to be efficient for traffic demand management (see, e.g., Yang et al. [1]; Lindsey [2]; Yang et al. [3]; Zhong et al. [4]; and the references therein). On the other hand, the signal control and ramp metering schemes are efficient for regulating the supply side of a transportation system.
The literature also argues that the traffic congestion and the inherent environmental pollution induced by vehicles in congested urban area should be regarded as external costs that control mechanisms can internalize. The market-based approaches advocated by some engineers and economists, including road pricing [5–7] and tradable travel (or pollution) permits/credits [3, 8, 9], are demonstrated to be efficient in reducing harmful traffic congestion and emissions. Also, the literature in road pricing investigation showed that road pricing methods could internalize the externalities such as traffic congestion, environmental pollution, and noise pollution [10–12]. Nevertheless, though road pricing schemes have been extensively studied by researchers, some fundamental drawbacks exist. From a theoretical point of view, perfect information on both the demand and supply sides of traffic networks is needed for implementation [5, 9]. Besides, though some advances are achieved in electronic tolling collection technology, the pricing scheme is still inequitable and costly [3, 5]. The general political and public resistance to congestion charges is another important reason to prevent road pricing from being practical. Because of this, planners and researchers have turned to quantity control to avoid the general resistance to road pricing. The quantity control schemes aim to restrict the number of private vehicles on the network by managing the travel demand of the traffic system and assigning mobility rights to individual travellers. Simple quantity control schemes include the temporary plate number-based traffic rationing and some long-term implementations of road space rationing, which are practically enforced in China and Latin America [13]. It is reported by Han et al. [13] and Wang et al. [14] that a short-term rationing policy can substantially reduce congestion and improve air quality. However, a long-term traffic rationing policy would implicitly promote undesirable second-car ownership for circumventing the restriction, which may decrease the effectiveness of the rationing policy over time.
The tradable network permit/credit schemes, which have been systematically introduced by Yang et al. [3], ensure the goal that the congestion on the network can be reduced by issuing a certain number of network travel credits and/or imposing capacity constraints on the bottlenecks. Yang et al. [3] further formulate the combined problem as some standard traffic assignment problems subject to a total credit consumption constraint (with/without side constraints). Researchers describe tradable permit/credit schemes as cap-and-trade schemes. In this scheme, the system manager first sets the cap (policy target) in quantity (total number of permits/credits) and distributes a certain number of access tickets (permits/credits) to all eligible users. After this, the users can access the competitive links (or bottlenecks) by paying a link-specific number of tickets (permits/credits) and trade the tickets in a competitive and efficient market. The price for these permits/credits is determined by the trade market. It is claimed by Yang et al. [3] that this kind of cap-and-trade scheme involves at least the same equity as a strict rationing policy. The serious political resistance to road pricing can be avoided as this tradable credit scheme involves no financial transfer from travellers to the government. Some other tradable pollution permit schemes are also investigated; see, e.g., Raux [15]; Raux and Marlot [16]; Perrels [17]; Wadud et al. [18]; and Wadud [19]. Though these categories of traffic management and control schemes are investigated independently, the traffic authority would implement a hybrid of them simultaneously in practice, e.g., road pricing and traffic flow regulation. Thus, evaluating the performance of hybrid control schemes is important for transportation management [20, 21]. In particular, we would investigate the hybrid combination of road pricing and quantity control methods.
In the previous studies of congestion pricing [11, 22, 23] and travel permit/credit [3, 24, 25], the network is assumed to be managed by a central authority that aims to improve the efficiency of the whole transportation network. In this case, the transportation network is regarded as a closed system with boundaries, which may be unrealistic in practice as there would be cross-boundary traffic (also known as through traffic) crossing the local network [26–28]. Generally, there are multiple administrative regions at a federal/state level, with each local region authority aiming to maximize the social welfare of its own region when designing management strategies. For example, special administrative cities such as Macao and Hong Kong that have well-defined geographical limits would maximize the social welfare of their local region. On the other hand, cross-boundary traffic is needed for the local authority to satisfy the requirements of economic activities such as tourism and logistics. In this study, we consider the problem that a local authority intends to maximize the social welfare of the local region by tradable credit schemes considering the cross-boundary traffic. The problem considered in this study is similar to the multi-criteria mixed equilibrium problem for multi-class traffic on networks and the subsequent anonymous link toll design for system optimum [8, 29, 30].
The remainder of this study is organized as follows. In Section 2, we first discuss the system optimum problem of the local traffic network by link-specific optimal tolls, wherein the quantity of the cross-boundary traffic is controlled by the local authority. We then design tradable credit schemes to realize specific desirable network flow patterns (such as local system optimum). To be specific, two credit charging schemes are investigated in Section 3, i.e., a spatially differentiated credit scheme and an anonymous tradable credit scheme. In the first scheme, due to the different charging prices and the selfishness of the local authority, the travel credit is freely tradable within the local travellers only. The cross-boundary travellers have to buy travel credits from the local authority. In the second scheme, the tradable credit scheme is anonymous. The local authority determines the link-specific number of credits to be charged for using that link, while the travel credits are distributed to local travellers only but are allowed for free trading among both local and cross-boundary travellers. The uniqueness of the market price of the travel credits is shown under certain assumptions. Numerical experiments are conducted in Section 4 to demonstrate the theoretical development. Conclusions are then discussed.
2. Local System Optimum Problem Formulation and Optimal Tolling Solution
Before summarizing the results in detail, let us look into some special cases.
Remark 1. If the side constraints (5) are inactive, according to the slackness conditions (12), τ = 0 can be guaranteed. In this case, one may write the equilibrium condition (18) according to different sets of OD pairs as follows:
The above two conditions are similar to those of multi-class mixed equilibrium conditions for Cournot–Nash (CN) players proposed by Yang and Zhang [29] and Han and Yuan [31], wherein a CN player aims to minimize the total travel time of the users under this specific player based on the routing strategies of other users. In other words, the player designs its flow patterns by taking the flow patterns of other players as fixed (or constant). The mixed traffic case is taken as an example, in which either the local traffic v1 or cross-boundary traffic v2 is a decision variable in the CN game. However, in our case, both of them are decision variables simultaneously.
The revenue function of the cross-boundary traffic is in a position closely analogous to the marginal benefit function of the local traffic. The amplitude of this function, i.e., revenue made from a unit external trip, reveals the marginal benefit contributed by the cross-boundary traffic, which serves as a basis for the local authority to determine how many trips should be permitted. From the equilibrium condition (18), we note that the system optimal toll for cross-boundary traffic is generally higher than that for local traffic, where the local traffic is charged by the marginal cost pricing, i.e., . This is because the local authority tries to maximize its own social welfare (selfish planning to protect the interest of local residents) rather than that of both local traffic and cross-boundary traffic, which is similar to the infrastructure investment problem for a region that faces much cross-boundary traffic (or through traffic) [26, 27, 32]. The literature argues that the regional authority generally cares about the welfare of the local users only when making decisions. It is unlikely for the regional authority to consider the utility of the infrastructure for external users. Thus, our model does not include the marginal benefit (demand function) of the cross-boundary traffic. On the other hand, a local authority has limited incentives to invest if it cannot make a sufficiently large revenue from the cross-boundary [32]. The regional authority also has an incentive to raise the user charge above the marginal cost for external users or the so-called tax exporting behaviour [27, 32], which, in our case, is τ.
Remark 2. The cross-boundary trips can contribute to the local economy, e.g., tourism and logistics. The incentive of the local authority to permit the cross-boundary users is to make a revenue that fully compensates the total marginal social cost, i.e., , induced by the cross-boundary traffic to the local network. Given a quantity of cross-boundary trips , the total revenue perceived by the local authority is . Let us define the following amount:
If all the cross-boundary traffic flows on the network are without the side constraints (5), then according to (20), △e = 0. That is, the local authority can compensate for the total marginal social cost induced by the cross-boundary traffic to make a traffic state as good as the case without cross-boundary trips [32]. The toll is designed in a revenue-neutral manner. However, as certain road capacity needs to be allocated for cross-boundary traffic, it seems to be unfair to the local residents. For instance, certain links with high revenue may be fully occupied by cross-boundary traffic in extreme cases. To provide an acceptable network condition for the local traffic, side constraints are set for the cross-boundary traffic and additional tolls are enforced to the external users. Under this case, according to (18), we have △e ≥ 0. This amount of monopoly revenue can be viewed as compensation for the capacity loss of local travellers caused by the cross-boundary trips.
The argument in the above remark can be read as follows: since the local authority cares about its local social welfare only, it will not permit cross-boundary trips if the revenue function of the cross-boundary trips is not significant (large enough). On the other hand, even though the revenue function is large enough, the local authority would not encourage a large quantity of cross-boundary trips as it needs to protect the travel right of the local residents.
3. Two Tradable Credit Schemes
Having characterized the equilibrium condition with both local traffic and cross-boundary traffic, we investigate two credit charging schemes (local tradable credit scheme and freely tradable credit scheme) to achieve such desired traffic pattern in this section.
3.1. Local Tradable Credit Scheme
Therefore, the equilibrium market price remains equal to unity for any system optimal local credit scheme (K1, κ1). Besides, the total market value of all credits is constant at p1∗K1∗. This result is consistent with that of Yang et al. [3], which is due to the fact that the authority allows the local users to trade travel credits within the local market only. Given a credit charging scheme (K1, κ1), the market credit price p1∗ and credit market value for local traffic are unique. We summarize this in the following proposition.
Proposition 1. Assume that the local authority issue travel credits for the local and cross-boundary users separately and independently. Assume further that only local users are allowed to trade their credits freely in the market and the cross-boundary users are restricted to buy credits from the local authority with a link-specific credit charge according to . Then, any tradable credit scheme contained in the following nonempty polyhedron can decentralize a given system optimal flow pattern (v1∗, d∗) for the local traffic:
Remark 3. We did not enforce a market clearing condition for the cross-boundary traffic. There is no credit market for the cross-boundary traffic as the cross-boundary users have to buy credits from the local authority only. The mechanism for cross-boundary traffic is more like that of road pricing. The local authority’s incentive for cross-boundary traffic to use its traffic network depends on the revenue it can receive from the cross-boundary trips, as explained in the previous section. The larger revenue the local authority can obtain from a unit cross-boundary trip, the larger quantity of cross-boundary trips is well received. Also, the local authority tends to provide an acceptable network condition for local traffic1, which is captured by the side constraints imposed on the cross-boundary traffic.
3.2. Freely Tradable Credit Scheme
Yang et al. [29] and Han et al. [31] proposed system optimum tolls for networks with multi-class multi-criteria mixed equilibrium behaviours. To internalize their full externality, each UE user is charged with a marginal cost toll equals . In contrast, each user under a specific Cournot–Nash player who has already taken account of his partial externality is charged with a partial marginal cost toll equals , wherein is the volume of link a contributed by vehicles of class k. The partial marginal cost toll can internalize the additional externality that the users under a Cournot–Nash player impose on UE users and users under other players. This renders different system optimum link tolls for users under different players, including the UE player. Furthermore, it was commented by Yang et al. [29] that as all users on networks behave indistinguishably, such link toll differentiation across user classes is hard to be implemented. Also, the nonuniqueness issue arises for the link tolls with different user classes. Nevertheless, observing that the aggregate system optimal link volumes are unique under certain assumptions, it is possible to pursue anonymous link tolls on networks with multi-class multi-criteria mixed equilibrium behaviours to achieve system optimum.
Proposition 2. Let be the Lagrange multipliers associated with the link flow constraint (31) for the programs (30)–(39), and then, are the anonymous link tolls.
Therefore, the equilibrium market price remains equal to unity for any system optimal credit scheme (K∗, κ∗). We summarize the result as follows.
Proposition 3. Any tradable credit scheme contained in the following nonempty polyhedron can decentralize a given system optimal flow pattern (v∗, d∗, de∗):
- (1)
The objective of the local authority in the freely tradable credit scheme is to pursue a predetermined system optimum link flow pattern and to design credit charging schemes according to this link flow pattern. Two vehicle classes, , are anonymous to the local authority.
- (2)
Travel credits are distributed to local users only. However, any user willing to pay the anonymous link tolls or credit charges can travel on the network.
- (3)
The local authority does not have the power to control or affect this free credit market. The two groups of users can trade their travel credits according to their needs and favours.
Remark 4. We proceed with the analysis in Remark 2. Under the freely tradable credit scheme, △e defined by (21) equals zero, as the equilibrium conditions (45)–(48) can be given as follows:
It is clear that the local authority is designing tolls according to the elasticity of the local travel demand and the revenue made by the cross-boundary traffic. This is interesting and important as the local authority aims to maximize its local social welfare, implying that the elasticity of the cross-boundary traffic is not critical. Finally, we would like to mention that this result is consistent with the findings in the urban economics research; see, e.g., De Borger et al. [32]; Ubbels et al. [26]; and De Borger et al. [27]. It is proven in these papers that, for a single corridor with cross-boundary traffic, the regional authority can always stick to the policy that produces at least the same regional welfare as before (i.e., the case without cross-boundary traffic) as long as it can control the pricing and investment decisions. In our case, the local authority designs optimal tolls to compensate for the total marginal social cost induced by the cross-boundary traffic according to the revenue it contributes. On the other hand, according to programs (30)–(39) the local government can choose the set of local system optimal link volumes as to the target flow pattern and set the tolls or credit charges accordingly. Practically, the anonymous tradable credit scheme offers the policy with better political feasibility, as this tradable credit scheme involves no financial transfer from travellers to the government.
4. Numerical Experiments
4.1. Comparison of Two Credit Charging Schemes

For the local traffic on the network, there are two OD pairs (1⟶3 and 2⟶3), whose demands are assumed to be linear and given by d13 = 100 × (20 − π13) and d23 = 100 × (20 − π23), where πpq denotes the minimum OD travel cost. The inverse demand function is thus given by B13 = 20 − 1/100d13 and B23 = 20 − 1/100d23. We assume that nodes 1 and 3 are boundary nodes and node 2 is the center (or internal node) of the network. The cross-boundary vehicles can enter the network from node 1 and exit from node 3 by link 1 only. Therefore, the cross-boundary traffic has an OD pair 1⟶3. We further assume that the revenue function of the cross-boundary traffic is given by . By solving the system optimal traffic assignment without cross-boundary traffic, the optimal link volume vector is given by vso = [3.4913 0 5.9208 9.9208]T.
Here, we test the anonymous credit scheme first, in which the local authority initially distributes credits to all eligible local travellers only and allows for free trading among both local and cross-boundary travellers. The optimal link pattern for local traffic is given by v1,so = [1.3986 0 5.9208 9.9208]T. Note that the other OD pairs remain unchanged except for OD pair 1⟶3 as the cross-boundary traffic does not affect them. The optimal link pattern for cross-boundary traffic is v2,so = [2.0979 0 0 0]T. The credit charges are anonymous and are given by κ1 = 6.9930, κ3 = 5.9208, and κ4 = 9.9208. As can be seen, the cross-boundary traffic volume on link 1 is larger than the local traffic volume, which may be unacceptable to the local residents. However, the anonymous tradable credit scheme cannot set discriminatory tolls for local traffic and cross-boundary traffic. Thus, it cannot provide an acceptable condition for the local traffic.
We then test the local tradable credit scheme, in which only the local users are allowed to trade their credits in the market, and the external users need to buy credits from the local authority to travel on the network. To provide an acceptable condition for the local traffic, the local authority can impose a side constraint on the cross-boundary traffic volume. By solving the credit design program, we have that the side constraint will be violated. Under this case, the link volume of the local traffic is given by v1,so = [2.4938 0 5.9208 9.9208]T with the cross-boundary traffic given by the upper bound of the side constraint. Now, by the local tradable credit scheme, the credit charges for the two classes of users are κ1 = 6.9875, , κ3 = 5.9208, and κ4 = 9.9208. The local authority will distribute a number of credits equals to the local users, while the cross-boundary users need to buy credits from the authority by . The local users then can trade the credits in the local credit market.
4.2. Local Social Welfare under Tradable Credit Schemes

Link # | Ca | |
---|---|---|
1 | 6 | 200 |
2 | 5 | 200 |
3 | 6 | 200 |
4 | 7 | 200 |
5 | 6 | 150 |
6 | 1 | 150 |
7 | 5 | 150 |
8 | 10 | 200 |
9 | 11 | 200 |
10 | 11 | 200 |
11 | 15 | 200 |
Without tradable credit schemes, both local and external users choose their routes according to the actual travel time and demand elasticity. In this case, the equilibrium condition is the well-known user equilibrium, under which the transportation network would operate at low efficiency. In contrast, the tradable credit schemes can drive the system from user equilibrium to system optimum, under which the transportation network can operate at its highest efficiency. Furthermore, the local authority can maximize its local social welfare by determining the quantity of cross-boundary trips through the revenue function. The equilibrium link flow patterns with or without tradable credit schemes are presented in Table 2, wherein 2e is the link flow pattern for the cross-boundary traffic. As can be seen, the tradable credit schemes can control the quantity of cross-boundary trips so that the cross-boundary traffic would not damage the social welfare of the local region.
Patterns/link | 1 | 2 | 2e | 3 | 4 | 5 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Without control | 224.60 | 37.62 | 177.38 | 257.78 | 258.13 | 104.50 |
With control | 161.23 | 71.35 | 45.29 | 206.51 | 211.63 | 106.75 |
Patterns /link | 6 | 7 | 8 | 9 | 10 | 11 |
Without control | 220.51 | 33.18 | 152.94 | 156.23 | 221.58 | 159.73 |
With control | 140.28 | 45.28 | 121.29 | 168.49 | 177.74 | 154.59 |
The social welfare of the local traffic can be defined as , while the welfare contributed by the cross-boundary traffic is defined in Remark 1 as △e. Without tradable credit schemes, the social welfare of the local traffic is 2.6089 × 104, while the welfare contributed by the cross-boundary traffic is −1.1042 × 103, which means the cross-boundary traffic has caused welfare loss to the local region, which is unwanted for the local authority. After introducing tradable credit schemes, the social welfare of the local traffic becomes 2.7102 × 104, while the welfare contributed by the cross-boundary traffic is 0, which means the revenue of the cross-boundary traffic can compensate for the total marginal social cost induced by it. Meanwhile, the local social welfare increases as the tradable credit schemes can pursue a system optimum flow pattern.
5. Conclusions
This study extended the tradable travel credit schemes to the mixed local and cross-boundary traffic case. The problems were formulated as optimization programs wherein the local authority aims to maximize its local social welfare and pursue a specific set of system optimal link flow patterns. As we assumed that the local authority aims to maximize its local social welfare, the quantity of cross-boundary trips was determined by evaluating the revenue of the cross-boundary traffic. Link-specific optimal tolls were obtained by solving these programs. We then designed two credit charging schemes to achieve a given system optimal flow pattern, i.e., a spatially differentiated credit scheme and an anonymous tradable credit scheme. In the first scheme, the local traffic and cross-boundary traffic are charged with different local system optimal tolls, while the travel credits are freely tradable within the local travellers only. The cross-boundary travellers have to buy travel credits from the local authority. In the second scheme, the tradable credit scheme is anonymous. The local authority determines the link-specific number of credits to be charged for using that link, while the travel credits are distributed to local travellers only but are allowed for free trading among both local and cross-boundary travellers. The equilibrium link flow patterns under these credit schemes are demonstrated with local elastic demand. In both tradable credit schemes, the credit price in the trading market is unique under the equilibrium condition. The first scheme offers more regulatory power to control the volume of the cross-boundary traffic, as the local authority can set side constraints for the cross-boundary traffic. On the other hand, the second scheme is more practical and feasible, as this tradable credit scheme involves no financial transfer from travellers to the government. Numerical results show that the tradable credit schemes can significantly improve the local social welfare while resolving the welfare loss caused by the cross-boundary traffic. In particular, the spatially differentiated credit scheme can provide an acceptable network condition for the local traffic by setting side constraints for the cross-boundary traffic and enforcing additional tolls to external users.
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.
Acknowledgments
This study gratefully acknowledged financial support from the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Project 72071214).
Open Research
Data Availability
No data were used to support this study.