A Generic Decomposition Formula for Pricing Vanilla Options under Stochastic Volatility Models
Abstract
We obtain a decomposition of the call option price for a very general stochastic volatility diffusion model, extending a previous decomposition formula for the Heston model. We realize that a new term arises when the stock price does not follow an exponential model. The techniques used for this purpose are nonanticipative. In particular, we also see that equivalent results can be obtained by using Functional Itô Calculus. Using the same generalizing ideas, we also extend to nonexponential models the alternative call option price decomposition formula written in terms of the Malliavin derivative of the volatility process. Finally, we give a general expression for the derivative of the implied volatility under both the anticipative and the nonanticipative cases.
1. Introduction
Stochastic volatility models are a natural extension of the Black-Scholes model in order to manage the skew and the smile observed in real data. It is well known that in these models the average of future volatilities is a relevant quantity. See, for example, [1, Chapter 2]. Unfortunately, adding a stochastic volatility structure makes pricing and calibration more complicated, as closed formulas do not always exist. See, for example, [2], for a first reference on this topic. Moreover, even when these formulas exist, like for the Heston model (see [3]), in general, they do not allow a fast calibration of the parameters.
During last years, different developments for finding approximations to the closed-form option pricing formulas have been published. Malliavin techniques are naturally used to solve this problem in [4, 5] as the average future volatility is an anticipative quantity. Otherwise, a nonanticipative method to obtain an approximation of the pricing formula is developed for the Heston model in [6]. The method is based on the use of the adapted projection of the average future volatility. As a result, the model allows obtaining a decomposition of the call option price in terms of such future volatility.
In the present paper, we generalize [6] to general stochastic volatility diffusion models. Similarly, following the same kind of ideas, we extend the expansion based on Malliavin calculus obtained in [4, 5]. This is important because Heston model is not the unique stochastic volatility model currently used in practice, and some of them, like SABR model, are not of exponential type. For a general discussion about stochastic volatility models in practice, see [7].
- (i)
A generic call option price decomposition is found without having to specify the volatility structure.
- (ii)
A new term emerges when the stock option prices do not follow an exponential model, as, for example, in the SABR case.
- (iii)
The Feynman-Kac formula is a key element in the decomposition. It allows expressing the new terms that emerge under the new framework (i.e., stochastic volatility) as corrections of the Black-Scholes formula.
- (iv)
The decomposition found using Functional Itô calculus appears to be the same as the decomposition obtained through our techniques.
- (v)
A general expression of the derivative of the implied volatility, both for nonanticipative and anticipative cases, is given.
2. Notations
- (i)
Black-Scholes model: μ(t, S(t))≔rS(t), θ(t, S(t), σ(t))≔σS(t), ρ = 0, r > 0, and σ > 0.
- (ii)
CEV model: μ(t, S(t))≔rS(t), θ(t, S(t), σ(t))≔σS(t) β with β ∈ (0,1], ρ = 0, r > 0, and σ > 0.
- (iii)
Heston model: μ(t, S(t))≔rS(t), θ(t, S(t), σ(t))≔σ(t)S(t), r > 0, σ > 0, and
()where k, θ, and ν are positive constants satisfying the Feller condition 2kθ > ν2. - (iv)
SABR model: μ(t, S(t))≔rS(t), θ(t, S(t), σ(t))≔σ(t)S(t) β with β ∈ (0,1], r > 0, σ > 0, and
()with α > 0.
For existence and unicity of the solution in the Heston case, see, for example, [8, Section 2.2]. For the CEV and SABR models, see [9] and the references therein.
- (i)
We will denote by BS(t, S, σ) the price of a plain vanilla European call option under the classical Black-Scholes model with constant volatility σ, current stock price S, time to maturity τ = T − t, strike price K, and interest rate r. In this case,
()where Φ(·) denotes the cumulative probability function of the standard normal law and() - (ii)
We use in all the paper the notation , where is the natural filtration of S.
- (iii)
In our setting, the call option price is given by
() - (iv)
Recalling that from the Feynman-Kac formula, the operator
()satisfies . - (v)
We will also use the following definitions for y ≥ 0:
()
3. A Decomposition Formula Using Itô Calculus
In this section, following the ideas in [6], we extend the decomposition formula to a generic stochastic volatility diffusion process. We note that the new formula can be extended without having to specify the underlying volatility process, obtaining a more flexible decomposition formula. When the stock price does not follow an exponential process, a new term emerges. The formula proved in [6] is a particular case.
Theorem 1 (decomposition formula). For all t ∈ [0, T), we have
Proof. Notice that e−rTBS(T, S(T), v(T)) = e−rTV(T). As e−rtV(t) is a martingale, we can write
As the derivatives of BS are not bounded, we have to use an approximation to the identity changing BS(t, S, σ) by
So, applying Itô formula, using the fact that
Taking conditional expectation and multiplying by ert, we have
Remark 2. In [6], the following operators are defined for X(t) = log S(t):
- (i)
- (ii)
- (iii)
We observe the following:
- (i)
- (ii)
- (iii)
.
Remark 3. We have extended the decomposition formula in [6] to the generic SDE (1). When we apply Itô Calculus, we realize that Feynman-Kac formula absorbs some of the terms that emerge. It is important to note that this technique works for any payoff or any diffusion model satisfying Feynman-Kac formula.
Remark 4. Note that when θ(t, S(T), σ(t)) = σ(t)S(t) (i.e., the stock price follows an exponential process), then
Indeed, we show that, due to the use of Feynman-Kac formula,
4. Basic Elements of Functional Itô Calculus
In this section, we give the insights of the Functional Itô Calculus developed in [10–13].
Under this framework, we have the next definitions of derivative.
Definition 5 (horizontal derivative). The horizontal derivative of a functional at t is defined as
Definition 6 (vertical derivative). The vertical derivative of a functional at t is defined as
We also have the following Itô formula that works for nonanticipative functionals:
Theorem 7 (Functional Itô Formula). For any nonanticipative functional and any t ∈ [0, T], we have
5. A General Decomposition Using Functional Itô Calculus
In this section, we apply Functional Itô Calculus to the problem of finding a decomposition for the call option price. The decomposition problem is an anticipative path-dependent problem. Using a smart choice of the volatility process into the Black-Scholes formula, we can convert it into a nonanticipative one. It is natural to wonder whether the Functional Itô Calculus brings some new insides into the problem.
Under this framework, we calculate the derivatives using Functional Itô Calculus with respect to the variance. Then we write them in terms of the classical Black-Scholes derivatives. We must realize that, for simplicity, the new derivatives are calculated with respect to the variance instead of the volatility of the process.
Remark 8. If ∂ denotes the classical derivative, we have
- (i)
Alternative Vega:
() - (ii)
Alternative Vanna:
() - (iii)
Alternative Vomma:
() - (iv)
Alternative Theta:
()
Theorem 9 (decomposition formula). For all t ∈ [0, T), S(t), and , we have
Proof. Notice that . As e−rtV(t) is a martingale, we can write
We deduce that
Note that
- (i)
as S(t) is not path-dependent, we have that ∇S(·) = ∂S(·);
- (ii)
as u > t and f is a nonanticipative functional, then .
So, we have
Remark 10. Note that Functional Itô formula proved in [11] holds for semimartingales but in [12] is also proved for Dirichlet process. In both cases, the hypothesis hold by definition of f and differentiability of the derivatives of Black-Scholes function when τ, S, σ > 0. Therefore, this technique can be applied to these models.
Remark 11. Note that Theorem 9 coincides with Theorem 1 when we choose the volatility function as . We found an equivalence of the ideas developed by [6, 10–13] in the decomposition problem. Both formulas come from different points of view; the ideas under [10–13] are based on an extension to functionals of the work [14], while the main idea of [6] is to change a process by its expectation. Realize that standard Itô Calculus also can be applied to Dirichlet processes (for more information see [14]).
6. Basic Elements of Malliavin Calculus
In the next section, we present a brief introduction to the basic facts of Malliavin calculus. For more information, see [15].
We will use the next Itô formula for anticipative processes.
Proposition 13. Let us consider the processes , where . Furthermore, consider also a process , for some . Let be a twice continuously differentiable function such that there exists a positive constant C such that, for all t ∈ [0, T], F and its derivatives evaluated in (t, X(t), Y(t)) are bounded by C. Then it follows that
Proof. See [4].
The next proposition is useful when we want to calculate the Malliavin derivative.
Proposition 14. Let σ and b be continuously differential functions on with bounded derivatives. Consider the solution X = {Xt, t ∈ [0, T]} of the stochastic differential equation:
Proof. See [15, Section 2.2].
7. Decomposition Formula Using Malliavin Calculus
In this section, we use the Malliavin calculus to extend the call option price decomposition in an anticipative framework. This time, the decomposition formula has one term less than in the Itô formula’s setup.
Theorem 15 (decomposition formula). For all t ∈ [0, T), we have
Proof. Notice that . As e−rtV(t) is a martingale, we can write
Taking conditional expectation and multiplying by ert, we have
Remark 16. As it is expected, a new term emerges when it is considered (1) like it happens in Theorem 1.
Remark 17. In particular, when θ(t, S(T), σ(t)) = σ(t)S(t),
Remark 18. Note that when v(t) is a deterministic function, we have that all decomposition formulas are equal.
Remark 19. When ρ = 0, we have
8. An Expression for the Derivative of the Implied Volatility
In this section, we give a general expression for the derivative of the implied volatility under the framework of Itô Calculus and Malliavin calculus. A previous calculation of this derivative in the case of exponential models by using Malliavin calculus is given in [5].
Let I(S(t)) denote the implied volatility process, which satisfies by definition V(t) = BS(t, S(t), I(S(t))). We calculate the derivative of the implied volatility in the standard Itô case.
Proposition 20. Under (1), for every fixed t ∈ [0, T) and assuming that (v(t)) −1 < ∞ a.s., we have that
Proof. Taking partial derivatives with respect to S(t) on the expression V(t) = BS(t, S(t), I(S(T))), we obtain
Now, we derive the implied volatility using Malliavin calculus. This is done in [5] for the case θ(t, S(T), σ(t)) = σ(t)S(t).
Proposition 21. Under (1), for every fixed t ∈ [0, T) and assuming that a.s., we have that
Proof. See [5] or the previous proof.
Remark 22. Note that this is generalization of the formula proved in [5]. In that case, F1 = F2 and F3 = 0.
9. Examples
In this section, we provide some applications of the decomposition formula to well-known models in Finance.
9.1. Heston Model
9.2. SABR Model
10. Conclusion
In this paper, we notice that the idea used in [6] can be used for a generic Stochastic Differential Equation (SDE). There is no need to specify the volatility process. Only existence and uniqueness of the solution of the SDE are needed, allowing much more flexibility in the decomposition formula. We observe what is the effect of assuming that the stock price follows an exponential process and how a new term arises in a general framework. Additionally, we have computed the decomposition using three different methods: Itô formula, Functional Itô Calculus, and Malliavin calculus. In the case of call options, the idea used in [6] is equivalent to the use of the Functional Itô formula developed in [10–13] but without the need of the theory behind the Functional Itô Calculus. Both formulas can be applied to Dirichlet process, in particular, to the fractional Brownian motion with Hurst parameter equal or bigger than 1/2. Furthermore, we realize that the Feynman-Kac formula has a key role in the decomposition process.
Conflict of Interests
The authors declare that there is no conflict of interests regarding the publication of this paper.