Volume 38, Issue 1 pp. 193-229
Original Article
Full Access

Invoicing Currency in International Trade: An Empirical Investigation and Some Implications for the Renminbi

Edwin L.-C. Lai

Edwin L.-C. Lai

Department of Economics, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Kowloon, Hong Kong

Search for more papers by this author
Xiangrong Yu

Xiangrong Yu

Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research, Hong Kong Monetary Authority, Hong Kong, Hong Kong

Search for more papers by this author
First published: 24 October 2014
Citations: 16
We thank Hongyi Chen and Dong He, as well as seminar participants in the Hong Kong University of Science and Technology (HKUST), Hong Kong Monetary Authority, and the Fourth HKIMR Annual Conference on the Chinese Economy for helpful comments and discussions. We also thank Ken Wu and Jing Zhou for excellent research assistance. The work in this paper has been supported by a grant from the Center for Economic Development of HKUST.

Abstract

To play the role of a unit of account, an international currency must be a currency widely used to invoice international trade. This paper investigates the determinants of the use of currencies in trade invoicing and evaluates the potential of the renminbi for the denomination of cross-border transactions in the Asia-Pacific region. In particular, we develop a simple model and establish the evidence showing that there is a convex relationship between the invoicing share of a currency and the economic size of its issuing country because of a coalescing effect and thick market externalities. We use the ratio of the foreign exchange (FX) turnover share of a currency to the global GDP share of its issuing country as a proxy for the size of thick market externalities, which we argue reflects capital account openness, financial development and exchange rate stability of the country. This ratio is very small for the renminbi compared with the ratios for established international currencies. Our quantitative analysis suggests that the renminbi can be a major invoicing currency in the region only if China sufficiently opens up its capital account and liberalises its financial sector. We also draw a parallel between the renminbi and the euro and forecast the invoicing share of the renminbi in the Asia-Pacific region if the renminbi market attained the same degree of thickness as the euro.

1 Introduction

What determines the use of a currency in the invoicing of international trade? This question is non-trivial for the management of exchange rate risk at the firm level, but also has important implications for the transmission of macroeconomic shocks across economies, especially in the form of exchange rate pass-through. There are by and large three major functions of an international currency: a unit of account (for trade invoicing, denomination of financial products and exchange rate pegging), a medium of exchange (for settlement of trade and financial transactions, and foreign exchange (FX) market interventions) and a store of value (for saving and reserve holding). Reflecting its role as a unit of account, an international currency must be widely used to invoice cross-border trade transactions. Understanding the potential of a currency to be an invoicing currency will help shed light on the extent to which it can be used as an investment currency or a reserve currency, as the three functions are all related. The acceptance for trade invoicing is an essential dimension of the international status of a currency.

This question has become more relevant in recent years as the renminbi has been increasingly used outside of China, especially in the Asia-Pacific region, an immediate neighbour and close trading partner of China. The internationalisation of the renminbi was put on the policy agenda by the Chinese authorities in the aftermath of the global financial crisis of 2007–2009 (Chen and Cheung, 2011; Eichengreen, 2011; Ito, 2011; McCauley, 2011; Frankel, 2012; He, 2012; Yu, 2012). Since then, the restrictions against the use of the renminbi in current account transactions have been removed, and the scope for the use of the renminbi in capital account transactions has been gradually expanded.

Figure 1 shows an obvious and steep upward trend in the share of China's cross-border trade settled in the renminbi, from almost zero in 2009 to 16.6 per cent in the first three quarters of 2013. Of all renminbi-settled trade, however, only about 56 per cent was invoiced in the renminbi in 2012 (Li, 2013). There is empirical evidence that, in general, the currency used in invoicing is also the one used in actual payment (Friberg and Wilander, 2008). Thus, this disparity between settlement and invoicing is largely unique for the renminbi, showing that the government policy works in promoting renminbi settlement, but the market is still hesitant to use the renminbi as an invoicing currency. To put the scale of renminbi invoicing in perspective, consider the following figures (latest, to the best of our knowledge): about 99.8 per cent of the US exports and 92.8 per cent of the imports were invoiced in the dollar in 2003 (Goldberg and Tille, 2008), while 62.5 per cent of exports and 49 per cent of imports were invoiced in the euro in extra-euro area goods transactions of euro area countries in 2012 (ECB, 2013). Therefore, the share of the Chinese currency in invoicing China trade is small compared with the corresponding shares of US$ and euro in invoicing American and Eurozone trade, respectively. Moreover, when China is not involved in the trade, the use of the renminbi as a vehicle currency for trade invoicing would be much less. In contrast, the dollar as the primary vehicle currency accounts for a dominating share in the Asia-Pacific region and even in the euro area, and other established currencies also play non-trivial roles (Figures 2 and 3).

Details are in the caption following the image
Share of Renminbi Settlement in China's Cross-border Trade
  • Data Source: People's Bank of China.
Details are in the caption following the image
Invoicing Currency Distribution: Asia-Pacific
  • Source: Kamps (2006).
Details are in the caption following the image
Invoicing Currency Distribution: Eurozone
  • Source: Kamps (2006).

In short, the actual use of the renminbi as an invoicing currency remains very limited and seems to fall behind the overall progress in the internationalisation of the renminbi. It is therefore important to understand prospects for the renminbi as a major invoicing currency, at least in the Asia-Pacific region, and the factors that could impede the realisation of its potential.

Any research in this area is, however, constrained by the availability of data on invoicing behaviour. Because of the lack of historical data on renminbi invoicing, we cannot make predictions based on its past trend. The best we can do is to use the experience of some major currencies to benchmark the potential role of the renminbi under comparable economic and institutional conditions. Fortunately, we are able to construct two data sets that allow us to pursue this line of analysis.

We approach this problem from two angles. First, we focus on one country, namely Thailand, and investigate the determinants of the invoicing share of different currencies when it trades with various partner countries. Second, we focus on one currency, namely the euro, and investigate the determinants of its invoicing share in trade of various countries. We use empirical models estimated from these two types of regression analysis to gauge the extent to which the currency of interest, the renminbi, will be used to invoice international trade in the Asia-Pacific region, considering (i) the potential invoicing share of the renminbi in the trade of Thailand with China and ASEAN economies, and (ii) the projected use of the renminbi in invoicing the trade of Asia-Pacific countries such as Australia, the ASEAN countries and South Korea.

The above two methods address different aspects of the question of interest, but results are largely consistent with each other. The choice of Thailand is determined by the availability of the data as well as its relevance for the expansion of the cross-border use of the renminbi. As a typical Southeast Asian country, Thailand has close economic ties with China. China is now the largest trading partner of Thailand with a share of 12 per cent and 15 per cent in the total exports and imports, respectively, of Thailand in 2012. On the other hand, the choice of the euro is determined by the availability of the data as well as similarities with the renminbi as it emerged as a competitor with the dollar in Europe and its neighbouring regions. Interested in finding whether there is any historical experience of a currency that resembles the circumstances of the renminbi today, we think that the euro may be a good example. The euro was a new currency that emerged in the late 1990s, just like the renminbi is an emerging currency today. The circumstances in which the euro found itself then were somewhat like those for the renminbi today, that is, aspiring to be a regional currency that challenges the incumbent currency, the US dollar. While the euro challenged the dominance of the dollar in Europe, the renminbi may challenge the dollar in Asia.

We emphasise that we are estimating the potential of the renminbi conditional on it having comparable conditions as the reference currencies. In particular, we develop a simple theory for the determination of an invoicing currency, which implies a convex relationship between the invoicing share of a currency and the economic size of its issuing country. In our framework, it is the coalescing effect and thick market externalities that give rise to this convex relationship. We call this the ‘tipping phenomenon’ in invoicing currency and argue that thick market externalities can be attributed to the degree of capital account openness and financial market maturity of the issuing country. Our analysis of the Thai data finds some evidence of the tipping phenomenon and shows that the convexity between the invoicing share and the economic size is partly due to the size of thick market externalities, which is proxied by the ratio of FX turnover share of a currency to the GDP share of the issuing country (hereafter referred to as the FX-share-GDP-share ratio). This ratio is very small for the renminbi relative to the established currencies, such as the US dollar, euro, Japanese yen and pound sterling, reflecting the lack of capital account openness and immaturity of the financial sector in China. Our analysis of the euro data focuses only on one currency and hence cannot explicitly test the tipping phenomenon. Guided by our theory with the coalescing effect and thick market externalities, our empirical assessment of the renminbi's potential is conducted under the assumption of comparable capital mobility and well-functioning financial markets as in the euro area. To some extent, these estimates represent an upper bound of the renminbi's potential.

Taken together, our empirical estimates consistently suggest that the renminbi has the potential to become a major invoicing currency in the Asia-Pacific region. However, to arrive at the ‘tipping point’, China has to establish a market thickness for the renminbi comparable to that of established currencies. In other words, China needs to sufficiently open up its capital account and liberalise its financial sector to fully materialise the potential of the renminbi as an international invoicing currency.

2 Some Background Literature

There is a rich economic literature on the factors that determine the emergence of an international invoicing currency. Instead of carrying out a comprehensive survey, we provide a brief discussion on the two important forces behind our theoretical model in the context of the present paper.

Studying the currency denomination of international trade, Bacchetta and van Wincoop (2005) and Goldberg and Tille (2008) focus on the ‘unit of account’ function of money. In particular, Goldberg and Tille (2008) argue that exporting firms have the incentive to mimic the choice of invoicing currency of their competitors in the same market so as to minimise price volatility and maximise profits. They call this ‘coalescing effect’ and use it to explain why there is one single vehicle currency used in the world to invoice homogeneous commodities such as oil.

Another reason why countries converge to using one single currency for trade invoicing is network externalities. Matsuyama et al. (1993) and Rey (2001) focus on the ‘medium of exchange’ function of money and conclude that ‘thick market externalities’ are very important in the making of a vehicle currency. As firms have an incentive to adopt the currency used by a majority of firms, once a currency becomes sufficiently widely used, its role as a vehicle currency is self-justifying. Following Kindleberger (1981), Krugman (1984) draws an analogy between money and language. He argues that what makes English the world's lingua franca is not its simplicity or internal beauty, but its wide use. As a language becomes more widely used, it is more attractive for outsiders to use it as well, as they can use it to communicate with more people in the world. Likewise, a firm is more willing to use a currency for invoicing if other firms are already using it.

A currency with strong network externalities usually possesses a few competitive advantages over other currencies, such as lower transaction costs, higher degree of convertibility, more open financial asset transaction and accessible financial services offered. The network externalities become self-enforcing as more firms use that currency for invoicing. In other words, as more firms use that currency for invoicing, its network externalities increase, which, in turn, enhances the attractiveness of the currency as an invoicing currency.

The self-reinforcing mechanism may also be applied to the adoption of a reserve currency. Chinn and Frankel (2007, p. 291) find that there is a statistically significant nonlinear relationship between the currency share in official reserves and the GDP share of issuing countries. They call this the ‘tipping phenomenon’: ‘if one currency were to draw even and surpass another, the derivative of reserve currency use with respect to its determining variables (e.g. GDP share) would be higher in that range than in the vicinity of zero or in the range when the leading currency is unchallenged’. This point is demonstrated in Figure 4, which is borrowed from Chen et al. (2009). In this figure, the panel data points of the reserve currency share are plotted against the GDP share of the issuing country, for the US dollar, euro, Japanese yen and pound sterling for the period of 1999–2008. There is clearly a convex relationship between the two variables.

Details are in the caption following the image
Reserve Currency Share versus GDP Share
  • Source: Chen et al. (2009).

In this paper, we develop a simple model showing how the coalescing effect and thick market externalities work together to give rise to a convex relationship between the invoicing share of a currency and the economic size of the issuing country. Our empirical tests and evaluation of the renminbi's potential as a major invoicing currency in the Asia-Pacific region are carried out based on this theory.

3 A Simple Theory

3.1 Coalescing Effect with No Thick Market Externalities

To begin, let us denote a country by capital letter (e.g. J) and its currency by the lower case (e.g. j). Suppose there are many firms in each country, each selling a good to many different countries. Each firm chooses an invoicing currency in each market so as to maximise its profits. We assume that the unit of account is also the medium of exchange, so that the invoicing currency is also the settlement currency. A Nash equilibrium is then a set of invoicing strategies such that each firm has no incentive to change its invoicing currency in each market given the invoicing currencies chosen by its competitors in each market.

Due to the coalescing effect, a firm has an incentive to choose the same invoicing currency as its competitors to reduce output volatility and maximise profits. As a country grows larger relative to the rest of the world, firms have higher tendency to invoice in the country's currency so as to compete with local producers. As proved by Lai and Zhou (2012), the coalescing effect implies that the invoicing share of a currency increases at an increasing rate with the GDP share of the issuing country when the GDP share is sufficiently small.

Let ηj denote the global invoicing share of currency j and let Xj denote the GDP share of country j. Use function ηj = h(Xj) to describe the relation between the two variables. Then, we have the following:

Proposition 1.In the presence of the coalescing effect in invoicing behaviour, h(Xj) > 0 for any Xj ∈ [0, 1], and h′′(Xj) > 0 when Xj is sufficiently small.

The proof of Proposition 1 can be found in Lai and Zhou (2012). The proposition shows that the currency of a larger country has a higher global invoicing share; moreover, the global invoicing share of a currency increases at an increasing rate with the GDP share of the country when the latter is small. In other words, there is a convex relationship between the GDP share of the issuing country and the invoicing share of its currency for emerging economies.

3.2 Coalescing Effect with Thick Market Externalities

We now introduce thick market externalities into our framework. Let Tj stand for the thickness of the market for currency j, which can be affected by many factors, such as the degree of convertibility of j and the depth and breadth of the financial markets of country J We assume that thick market externalities enter into ηj as a multiplicative factor, that is,
urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0001
Therefore, as the market for a currency gets thicker, its invoicing share increases, holding other factors constant.
Further, let urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0002 denote a vector that captures the degree of convertibility of j, the depth and breadth of the financial markets of country J and all other factors that enhance currency j's functioning as an international currency. When financial markets are allowed to operate more freely, all components of urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0003 will be larger. For example, when there is relaxation of capital controls and financial market liberalisation, components of urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0004 become larger. We summarise this effect by assuming that:
urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0005
In other words, the market thickness of currency j increases with capital account openness and the level of financial development of the issuing country. This assumption is in line with the view expressed by Krugman (1984). He argued that a currency with strong network externalities usually possesses a few competitive advantages over other currencies, such as lower transaction costs, higher degree of convertibility, more open financial asset transaction and accessible financial services.

In the setting outlined above, the positive effect of the GDP share on the invoicing share is reinforced by a thicker market for the currency. We can further show the following result:

Proposition 2.In the presence of both the coalescing effect and thick market externalities in determining invoicing behaviour,

urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0006
with h(Xj) and urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0007 capturing the coalescing effect and thick market externalities, respectively. Then, urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0008 for any urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0009, and urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0010 when XJ is small. Moreover, since urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0011, urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0012.

The idea of Proposition 2 is illustrated in Figure 5. The solid curve shows the relationship between the invoicing share of an emerging currency j and the GDP share of its issuing country J when the vector urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0013 is given, that is, when the degree of financial development and capital account openness are given. The dotted curve shows how the solid curve shifts when both financial development and capital account openness increase.

Details are in the caption following the image
Thick Market Externalities, Coalescing Effect and Tipping Phenomenon

3.3 Tipping Phenomenon

Empirically, we proxy thick market externalities Tj by the ratio of the FX turnover share of j to the GDP share of J. As shown in Table 1, we find that there is a positive correlation between this FX-share-GDP-share ratio and the GDP share of J. Our interpretation is that financial development, capital account liberalisation and the degree of currency convertibility all increase in the GDP share, that is, urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0014. Moreover, this is consistent with historical experience: that the financial development of the major economies of the world deepened as their global importance increased.

Table 1. Correlation between GDP Share and Ratio of FX Turnover Share to GDP Share
1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013
Correlation 0.261 0.280 0.301 0.312 0.294 0.429

Notes

  • The GDP data are not yet available for 2013 when we wrote this paper. Given that GDP share changes only slowly, we use 2012 GDP share as a proxy when computing the correlation in the last column.
  • Data Source: BIS, World Bank.

An important implication of Proposition 2 is that the presence of thick market externalities, coupled with the fact that financial development is positively correlated with the relative size of an economy (i.e. urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0015), leads to a convex relationship between invoicing share ηj and GDP share Xj. That is, we can see that urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0016 even without controlling for urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0017.

Back to Figure 5, urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0018 implies that as country J’s GDP share increases, urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0019 also increases, and hence, its invoicing curve also shifts up. Suppose we start from the origin 0 of the diagram. Then, as Xj increases, ηj increases, not only because there is movement along the solid curve, but also because there is a shift of the curve. The first effect is the coalescing effect, while the second effect is the effect of thick market externalities.

The convexity of ηj in Xj is a manifestation of the tipping phenomenon. In Section 3a, we argued that urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0020 for small XJ when controlling for urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0021, because of the coalescing effect. When thick market externalities are also present, we expect the magnitude of urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0022 to become larger, as urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0023, and urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0024. Thus, the tipping phenomenon can be due to both the coalescing effect and thick market externalities. How strong these effects are is an empirical question. In the empirical analysis presented below, we will show that the lack of thick market externalities can lead to rather serious underuse of a currency as an invoicing currency.

4 Empirical Evidence

In this section, we investigate the determinants of the use of invoicing currencies guided by the model outlined above. For an empirical study of invoicing behaviour, data limitation is a major constraint. We approach this problem from two perspectives: The first considers the determinants of the invoicing share of different currencies in a country's trade with its partners, while the second examines the determinants of the use of one currency in the trade of various countries. We use a data set from the Bank of Thailand for the first analysis and a data set on the euro for the second.

4.1 Fixing Country and Varying Currencies: Determinants of Invoicing Share of Currencies Used in Thailand's Trade

4.1.1 Data

For comparison across multiple invoicing currencies, we use a data set from the Bank of Thailand that contains the distribution of settlement currencies for Thailand's export to and imports from major trading partners between 1993 and 2011. This is a rare, publicly available data set documenting the choice of market-determined settlement or invoicing currencies in a country over a reasonably long period of time. An obvious limitation of this data set is that it only covers the trade of Thailand, but this can also be an advantage. With one partner of the trade controlled for, we obtain a check on different acceptances of an international currency in different geographic areas.

As we suggested earlier, when the choice of settlement currency is market-determined, we can assume for practical purposes that the settlement currency is the invoicing currency as well. We will benchmark the potential of the renminbi as an invoicing currency based on the market-determined behaviour. We are interested in the role of the renminbi in the Asia-Pacific region, and so Thailand, as a typical Southeast Asian country, is very relevant for our purposes.

Invoicing currencies in our sample include major international currencies (US dollar, euro, Japanese yen and pound sterling), regional currencies (Canadian dollar, Thai baht, Singapore dollar and Malaysian ringgit) and historical currencies (German mark, French franc and Italian lira). The set of trading partners consists of 29 countries from the ASEAN, EU and NAFTA.

The main variable of interest is the invoicing share of a currency in Thailand's imports from or exports to a trading country. Explanatory variables include the characteristics of currencies (e.g. volatility of exchange rate), the characteristics of currency issuing countries (e.g. GDP share) and the characteristics of trading partners (e.g. amount of trade of the trading partner with issuing countries).

A more detailed description of currencies, partner countries and the definition and measurement of the variables, as well as the descriptive statistics of the data, can be found in Appendix A.

4.1.2 A Preliminary Look at the Data

Our theoretical analysis implies a nonlinear relationship between the currency invoicing share and the issuing country's GDP share due to the coalescing effect and thick market externalities. Such tipping phenomenon seems to show up in Figure 6. In Thailand's trade with the rest of the world, the invoicing share of a currency jumps to a dominating level as the GDP share of the issuing country increases up to around 20 per cent. Below the threshold, an increase in the GDP share does not have a large effect. In Thailand's trade with the EU, the non-linearity seems to be quadratic, which partly motivates our specification with a squared term of the issuing country's GDP share in our regression analysis presented below. However, in trade with ASEAN and NAFTA countries, such a quadratic relation does not seem to be visible. Thus, we try an alternative specification using a logistic transformation of the invoicing share to capture nonlinearities.

Details are in the caption following the image
Currency Invoicing Share and GDP Share

Figure 7 displays the invoicing share of major currencies. It is clear that the US dollar plays a dominant role in Thailand's trade with NAFTA, ASEAN and EU countries, in decreasing order of share. The local currency, the Thai baht, is used in trade with countries in different regions, which reflects the practice of producer currency pricing in exports and local currency pricing in imports. The euro is mainly used in trade with the EU, but at a non-trivial level. The Japanese yen actually plays a visible role not only in Thailand's trade with ASEAN countries but also in its trade with NAFTA countries, which reflects its international role as a vehicle currency. The pound sterling and German mark have non-trivial shares only in the Thailand-EU trade.

Details are in the caption following the image
Major Invoicing Currencies in Thailand's Trade

The US dollar plays a dominating role in invoicing Thailand's trade, regardless of whether the United States is the trading partner or not. As shown in Figure 8, this has not changed much in the past two decades. During the sample period, the invoicing share of the euro and Thai baht rose slowly. The share of the Japanese yen has been declining but remains as the second-most used currency for a typical ASEAN country such as Thailand. Figure 9 further shows the use of the US dollar in trade with countries from different regions. Except in trade with EU countries, where the euro plays an important role, the share of US dollar invoicing remains above 75 per cent. In trade with NAFTA countries, its share is consistently close to 1. The higher share of the US dollar in Thailand's exports to the EU relative to imports from the EU is consistent with the intuition behind Grassman's (1973) law that seller firms with more bargaining power will choose the home currency (the euro vs. Thai baht) to avoid exchange rate risk. In general, the data show that the pattern of trade invoicing is quite persistent over time.

Details are in the caption following the image
Major Invoicing Currencies in Thailand's Trade over Time
Details are in the caption following the image
The US Dollar as Invoicing Currency in Thailand's Trade

4.1.3 Regression Analysis

We now use regression analysis to examine the determinants of the extent to which a currency is used in trade invoicing. Our baseline specification is given by the following:
urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0025
where yit is the currency invoicing share in Thailand's imports from or exports to partner country i at time t, xit is a set of characteristics of the currency, and εit is the error term. Our focus is the effects of the factors underlying the invoicing behaviour as captured by β.

In theory, the economic size of the issuing country will affect the international use of a currency in trade invoicing through multiple channels. For example, a larger economy usually trades more, and pricing in its currency is obviously convenient to foreign firms trading with that country. The bargaining power of domestic firms tends to increase as their home country becomes relatively larger economically, and hence, the trade of that country is more likely to be invoiced in the home currency, so that domestic firms can avoid exchange rate risks. The choice of the invoicing currency in bilateral trade certainly also depends on the trade patterns of the two trading partners. When the issuing country has a lot of trade with each of the trading partners, the currency tends to be used more because of the coalescing effect. Further, as argued in Engel (2006), the choice of an invoicing currency is essentially an indexing problem: firms that set prices in advance choose to index their prices to the current exchange rate in view of the uncertainty about exchange rate movements. The extent to which the exchange rate of a currency co-moves with the exchange rate of the Thai baht and that of the trading partner's currency is important in the management of exchange rate risk, in addition to transaction costs and exchange rate volatility.

Table 2 presents the baseline ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of a simple linear model. In columns (1) and (2), we include only the GDP share of the issuing country and find evidence of its positive effects on the use of the currency in both Thailand's imports and exports. When we add the share of the issuing country in Thailand's and the partner's total trade to capture the pattern of trade, columns (3) and (4) show that the importance of the issuing country to the trading partners is positively associated with the use of the currency in the trade between two partners that are not the issuing country. This partly reflects the influences of vehicle currencies. Columns (5) and (6) introduce exchange rate variables. We find evidence for the positive role of exchange rate co-movement with the Thai baht, but not for the role of exchange rate co-movement with the trading partner's currency. Larger exchange rate volatility is associated with less use of the currency in trade invoicing. The coefficient on the bid-ask spread is not statistical significant, which may suggest that monetary transaction costs are not that important, compared with non-monetary transaction costs, such as the time it takes to buy and sell the currency in exchange for other currencies.

Table 2. Determinants of Currency Invoicing Share in Thailand's Trade: Baseline Estimation with Simple Linear Model
Sample Import (1) Export (2) Import (3) Export (4) Import (5) Export (6)
Issuer's GDP share 2.336 2.444 2.746 3.045 2.756 2.980
(0.153) (0.122) (0.143) (0.123) (0.157) (0.137)
Issuer's share in Thailand total trade 0.202 0.231 0.147 0.185
(0.024) (0.035) (0.037) (0.043)
Issuer's share in partner's total trade 0.225 0.134 0.222 0.150
(0.041) (0.065) (0.044) (0.056)
EX co-movement with THB 0.079 0.128
(0.015) (0.010)
EX co-movement with partner's currency 0.009 –0.023
(0.024) (0.018)
EX volatility –0.134 –0.226
(0.027) (0.027)
EX bid-ask spread –0.680 –0.785
(0.806) (0.704)
Constant –0.019 –0.022 –0.154 –0.172 –0.110 –0.093
(0.015) (0.015) (0.015) (0.029) (0.032) (0.032)
R-square 0.627 0.622 0.730 0.743 0.751 0.783
No. of observations 1,901 1,821 1,901 1,821 1,251 1,266

Notes

  • (i) Standard errors, clustered within trading partners, are reported in parentheses.
  • (ii) ***< 0.01 and **< 0.05.
The dependent variable yit is bounded between 0 and 1, but from a technical point of view, the linear specification used above does not address this constraint. It is standard practice in this situation to take a logistic transformation of yit but still impose the usual OLS assumptions. The formulation, which is given as follows, then has a logistic interpretation:
urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0026

Following Chinn and Frankel (2007), we adopt a log-transformed specification as this transformation can partially capture the persistence of the international use of currencies in this setting.

Table 3 shows the estimates of the log-transformed version of the same set of regressions as presented in Table 2. The main message from Table 2 follows here. In columns (5) and (6), the exchange rate bid-ask spread has a negative coefficient, but is only significant at the 10 per cent and 5 per cent level, respectively. The other variables largely behave the same way as in the simple linear version.

Table 3. Determinants of Currency Invoicing Share in Thailand's Trade: Baseline Estimation with Logistic Transformation
Sample Import (1) Export (2) Import (3) Export (4) Import (5) Export (6)
Issuer's GDP share 20.337 20.674 25.424 27.354 24.130 25.978
(1.269) (1.017) (1.055) (1.145) (1.339) (1.519)
Issuer's share in Thailand total trade 3.213 3.339 2.148 2.436
(0.243) (0.343) (0.332) (0.437)
Issuer's share in partner's total trade 3.635 2.775 3.627 2.949
(0.262) (0.463) (0.321) 0.405
EX co-movement with THB 0.629 0.969
(0.172) (0.068)
EX co-movement with partner's currency –0.011 –0.297
(0.235) (0.176)
EX volatility –1.115 –1.995
(0.288) (0.316)
EX bid-ask spread –14.252 –17.056
(7.508) (7.725)
Constant –4.818 –4.800 –6.996 –7.128 –6.170 –5.991
(0.183) (0.143) (0.166) (0.304) (0.381) (0.519)
R-square 0.546 0.546 0.716 0.694 0.726 0.736
No. of observations 1,893 1,820 1,722 1,649 1,247 1,265

Notes

  • (i) Standard errors, clustered within trading partners, are reported in parentheses.
  • (ii) ***< 0.01 and **< 0.05.

As shown in Figure 6, the relationship between the invoicing share and the GDP share does not seem to be linear. Our theory presented in Section 3 also predicts that the coalescing effect and thick market externalities can lead to the non-linearity between the two variables. One way to capture this feature is to introduce a squared term of the GDP share into our linear specifications. Non-linearity is of course embedded in the logistic specifications. In our empirical analysis, thick market externalities are proxied by the FX-share-GDP-share ratio. We argue that this variable is the driving force underlying the non-linearity, which we will test with the data. Further, domestic financial development is potentially another fundamental condition of the wide use of a currency in international trade invoicing.

Table 4 presents evidence on the nonlinearity and the role of thick market externalities and financial development. Columns (1) and (2) re-estimate the linear model without exchange rate co-movement with partner's currency and the exchange rate bid-ask spread, which appear insignificant in Table 2. The estimates are largely unchanged. Columns (3) and (4) document that, after adding the squared term of the GDP share, the invoicing share of a currency is convex in the GDP share of the issuing country, in both the import and export regressions. The coefficient on the squared GDP share is statistically and economically significant. The specification with the squared GDP share also fits the data better. When we include the FX-share-GDP-share ratio, as displayed in columns (5) and (6), the invoicing share becomes less convex in the GDP share, although the convexity remains. This is consistent with our theory. The coefficients on the FX-share-GDP-share ratio are positive and significant, which demonstrates the influence of thick market externalities. When we add the variable for financial development in columns (7) and (8), proxied by the capital market depth of the issuing country, the coefficients on the squared GDP share become statistically insignificant. Thus, financial openness and development largely give rise to the convexity between the invoicing share and the GDP share. When we drop the squared term in columns (9) and (10), the effect of market externalities becomes stronger. In columns (11) and (12), the removal of the squared term does not lead to much change over the results in columns (7) and (8). Columns (13) and (14) further test the effects of financial development, without controlling for thick market externalities.

Table 4. Determinants of Currency Invoicing Share in Thailand's Trade: Inclusion of Thick Market Externalities in the Linear Model
Sample Import (1) Export (2) Import (3) Export (4) Import (5) Export (6) Import (7) Export (8) Import (9) Export (10) Import (11) Export (12) Import (13) Export (14)
Issuer's GDP share 2.641 2.918 1.163 0.620 1.424 0.999 2.061 2.162 2.492 2.625 2.213 2.206 2.439 2.615
(0.139) (0.118) (0.407) (0.344) (0.429) (0.427) (0.331) (0.291) (0.146) (0.134) (0.143) (0.128) (0.131) (0.111)
Issuer's GDP share squared 4.880 7.664 3.484 5.358 0.537 0.159
(1.506) (1.183) (1.493) (1.291) (1.102) (0.851)
Issuer's share in Thailand total trade 0.167 0.185 0.115 0.109 0.351 0.430 0.426 0.563 0.399 0.505 0.434 0.565 0.207 0.267
(0.023) (0.031) (0.030) (0.036) (0.060) (0.081) (0.061) (0.057) (0.060) (0.086) (0.057) (0.054) (0.022) (0.032)
Issuer's share in partner's total trade 0.228 0.140 0.222 0.130 0.246 0.230 0.252 0.250 0.254 0.245 0.254 0.250 0.233 0.155
(0.041) (0.055) (0.044) (0.051) (0.056) (0.066) (0.052) (0.059) (0.054) (0.066) (0.051) (0.058) (0.044) (0.050)
EX co-movement with THB 0.066 0.110 0.061 0.092 0.009 0.014 0.019 0.037 0.013 0.024 0.020 0.037 0.076 0.120
(0.012) (0.010) (0.009) (0.007) (0.012) (0.013) (0.014) (0.012) (0.014) (0.016) (0.014) (0.013) (0.013) (0.009)
EX volatility –0.123 –0.203 –0.089 –0.136 –0.061 –0.111 –0.011 –0.026 –0.084 –0.157 –0.011 –0.026 –0.064 –0.097
(0.021) (0.024) (0.013) (0.015) (0.012) (0.022) (0.018) (0.019) (0.017) (0.034) (0.018) (0.019) (0.014) (0.018)
Ratio of FX turnover share to GDP share 0.143 0.189 0.111 0.130 0.150 0.203 0.110 0.130
(0.035) (0.048) (0.028) (0.038) (0.036) (0.053) (0.028) (0.038)
Issuer's capital market depth 0.111 0.194 0.117 0.196 0.077 0.132
(0.040) (0.021) (0.041) (0.022) (0.027) (0.018)
Constant –0.113 –0.117 –0.067 –0.048 –0.289 –0.335 –0.470 –0.660 –0.335 –0.406 –0.484 –0.664 –0.248 –0.358
(0.015) (0.026) (0.020) (0.023) (0.060) (0.097) (0.095) (0.069) (0.061) (0.105) (0.090) (0.065) (0.048) (0.038)
R-square 0.742 0.775 0.750 0.793 0.746 0.809 0.754 0.833 0.741 0.799 0.754 0.833 0.750 0.798
No. of observations 1,712 1,650 1,712 1,650 1,219 1,190 1,219 1,190 1,219 1,190 1,219 1,190 1,712 1,650

Notes

  • (i) Standard errors, clustered within trading partners, are reported in parentheses.
  • (ii) ***< 0.01, **< 0.05 and *< 0.1.

The estimates based on the log-transformed specification are reported in Table 5. Given the embedded non-linearity, we do not include the squared term. However, our empirical evidence continues to support the importance of thick market externalities and financial development for the choice of the invoicing currency. In addition to the fact that yit is bounded between 0 and 1, we observe that a large proportion of trade activities is invoiced in the US dollar. With this skewed distribution, the OLS coefficient estimates are unbiased but no longer efficient, and in small samples, the standard errors may be biased. Fortunately, we have a relatively large sample, which can partially alleviate the concern. Taking the log-transformation, the sample distribution becomes much less skewed. From this perspective, the logistic version is our preferred specification. Thus, we draw implications for the renminbi based on the results in Table 5.

Table 5. Determinants of Currency Invoicing Share in Thailand's Trade: Inclusion of Thick Market Externalities in the Logistic Model
Sample Import (1) Export (2) Import (3) Export (4) Import (5) Export (6) Import (7) Export (8)
Issuer's GDP share 24.441 26.088 23.755 23.356 21.891 21.066 23.130 24.323
(1.087) (1.133) (1.157) (1.308) (1.313) (1.492) (1.122) (1.272)
Issuer's share in Thailand total trade 2.881 2.975 5.006 6.022 5.245 6.351 3.144 3.454
(0.242) (0.315) (0.528) (0.538) (0.497) (0.429) (0.260) (0.341)
Issuer's share in partner's total trade 3.668 2.830 3.783 3.566 3.779 3.596 3.698 2.915
(0.252) (0.386) (0.321) (0.432) (0.314) (0.427) (0.263) (0.356)
EX co-movement with THB 0.608 0.858 0.222 0.167 0.264 0.240 0.669 0.918
(0.115) (0.066) (0.137) (0.119) (0.137) (0.101) (0.129) (0.072)
EX volatility –1.129 –1.923 –0.930 –1.570 –0.443 –0.852 –0.744 –1.307
(0.213) (0.247) (0.192) (0.239) (0.211) (0.209) (0.197) (0.199)
Ratio of FX turnover share to GDP share 1.191 1.826 0.923 1.425
(0.291) (0.356) (0.225) (0.270)
Issuer's capital market depth 0.784 1.069 0.504 0.772
(0.343) (0.198) (0.239) (0.181)
Constant –6.615 –6.489 –8.47 –9.042 –9.472 –10.456 –7.495 –7.901
(0.224) (0.318) (0.507) (0.533) (0.741) (0.463) (0.486) (0.354)
R-square 0.727 0.726 0.750 0.789 0.757 0.802 0.732 0.735
No. of observations 1,704 1,649 1,215 1,190 1,215 1,190 1,704 1,649

Notes

  • (i) Standard errors, clustered within trading partners, are reported in parentheses.
  • (ii) ***< 0.01, **< 0.05 and *< 0.1.

Finally, our sample period covers two major financial crises, the Asian financial crisis and the recent global financial crisis. Does this fact affect our regression results? Figure 10 exhibits the trend of imports and exports of Thailand over time. The trade was not interrupted by the Asian financial crisis, at least at the aggregate level, but was somewhat affected by the recent crisis. As shown in Figure 8, the pattern of invoicing behaviour has persisted through the financial crises. When we re-estimate the preferred logistic model using the subsample that excludes observations for 1997–99 and 2008–10, the regression results, presented in Table 6, are almost the same as before, in terms of both statistical significance and magnitude. In other words, our main empirical results are robust to the inclusion of years during economic crises. Since we are interested in the long-term potential of the renminbi that can withstand economic fluctuations and crises, we use the estimates based on the whole sample (without omitting the observations of crisis years), as the benchmark for counterfactual evaluation of the potential use of the renminbi for trade invoicing in a country similar to Thailand, such as other ASEAN countries.

Table 6. Re-Estimation of the Logistic Model with Thick Market Externalities Excluding Financial Crises
Sample Import (1) Export (2) Import (3) Export (4) Import (5) Export (6) Import (7) Export (8)
Issuer's GDP share 24.114 25.159 23.579 22.518 21.670 20.627 23.289 24.240
(1.131) (1.220) (1.187) (1.409) (1.323) (1.562) (1.163) (1.259)
Issuer's share in Thailand total trade 2.767 2.624 5.045 6.177 5.154 6.433 3.074 3.103
(0.268) (0.354) (0.647) (0.638) (0.544) (0.478) (0.263) (0.377)
Issuer's share in partner's total trade 3.675 2.776 3.755 3.557 3.712 3.575 3.700 2.837
(0.251) (0.372) (0.320) (0.472) (0.307) (0.462) (0.260) (0.358)
EX co-movement with THB 0.693 1.110 0.054 0.026 0.267 0.240 0.793 1.235
(0.145) (0.095) (0.129) (0.113) (0.146) (0.107) (0.165) (0.124)
EX volatility –1.433 –2.789 –1.335 –1.908 –0.424 –0.745 –0.673 –1.696
(0.623) (0.596) (0.540) (0.448) (0.290) (0.210) (0.413) (0.554)
Ratio of FX turnover share to GDP share 1.069 1.898 0.564 1.338
(0.381) (0.454) (0.276) (0.331)
Issuer's capital market depth 1.007 1.163 0.471 0.644
(0.362) (0.238) (0.205) (0.192)
Constant –6.607 –6.247 –8.171 –8.982 –9.500 –10.681 –7.698 –7.815
(0.372) (0.482) (0.721) (0.785) (0.775) (0.591) (0.417) (0.566)
R-square 0.719 0.714 0.741 0.785 0.752 0.800 0.722 0.720
No. of observations 1,158 1,124 778 765 778 765 1,158 1,124

Notes

  • (i) Observations for 1997–99 and 2008–10 are excluded.
  • (ii) Standard errors, clustered within trading partners, are reported in parentheses.
  • (iii) ***< 0.01, **< 0.05 and *< 0.1.
Details are in the caption following the image
International Trade of Thailand from 1995 to 2012
  • Data Source: Bank of Thailand.

4.2 Fixing Currency and Varying Countries: Determinants of Invoicing Share of the Euro across Countries

4.2.1 Data

To understand how the extent to which a currency is used for trade invoicing varies across countries, we focus on the experience of the euro. Our data are mainly from the report The International Role of the Euro (ECB, 2011), supplemented by reports from central banks of individual countries (e.g. United Kingdom, Australia and Thailand) and compiled by us. We have collected information on the annual use of the euro in trade invoicing at the country level. There are 35 countries covered in these data: nine euro area countries (Belgium, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain), 14 European Union accession countries (Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia and United Kingdom), two European Union candidate countries (Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia and Turkey), one other European country (Ukraine) and nine countries outside Europe (Algeria, Australia, India, Indonesia, Pakistan, South Africa, Korea, Thailand and Tunisia). The period of coverage is 1999–2010. The earliest observations we use are from 1999 when the euro is introduced, and the latest observations are in 2010 (unbalanced panel). As far as we know, this is one of the most comprehensive data sets on euro invoicing across countries.

In this part of our analysis, the dependent variable is the invoicing share of the euro in the annual imports or exports of a country at an aggregate level. We do not observe invoicing shares in bilateral trade as in the Thailand data. To explain variations in the use of the euro across country and over time, the independent variables mainly include the characteristics of relevant countries (e.g. EU membership and economic size) and the euro (e.g. bid-ask spread). Appendix B contains a more detailed description of our data.

4.2.2 A Preliminary Look at the Data

The use of the euro for trade invoicing is shown in Table 7, along with US dollar invoicing. The first (third) column shows the euro share in the invoicing of exports (imports), averaged across the available observations in the sample period for each country. Similarly, the second (fourth) column shows the dollar share in export (import) invoicing, for which we have constructed a comparable data set for the role of the US dollar. For countries in the Eurozone, the euro is their local currency and typically amounts to a share over 50 per cent. For other European countries (except Ukraine), EU member or not, the euro also plays a significant role, which is at least comparable to the role of the US dollar. However, the US dollar overwhelmingly dominates both export and import invoicing in all non-European countries with observations in our sample. The different pictures are partly captured by the EU dummy that is included in the regression analysis presented below. Overall, the US dollar is the prominent invoicing currency globally.

Table 7. Use of the Euro and the US Dollar for Invoicing in Exports and Imports of Different Countries
Export Import
Euro Share (%) US$ Share (%) Euro Share (%) US$ Share (%)
European countries
Belgium 53.630 30.967 53.730 34.200
Bulgaria 53.200 50.186 58.369 42.886
Croatia 69.192 31.057 73.917 22.214
Cyprus 18.550 9.950
Czech Republic 71.642 13.633 68.208 19.217
Denmark 32.883 21.950 33.900 20.450
Estonia 60.925 9.200 58.388 21.950
France 50.325 37.940 43.142 48.680
Germany 61.717 26.600 54.833 34.767
Greece 37.930 54.350 35.960 57.150
Hungary 78.643 16.400 69.857 21.343
Italy 61.609 24.800 45.664 34.300
Latvia 50.709 39.600 56.536 35.660
Lithuania 46.342 50.029 49.092 47.700
Luxembourg 52.691 29.000 43.664 40.233
Macedonia, FYR 68.167 35.800 67.242 33.714
Netherlands 49.560 35.940 41.900 47.000
Poland 62.942 31.829 58.250 30.571
Portugal 54.118 31.725 53.609 34.725
Romania 63.425 36.357 67.167 30.914
Slovakia 74.663 25.400 78.800
Slovenia 83.230 9.580 74.870 14.860
Spain 57.869 35.614 54.223 41.714
Turkey 47.767 43.467 36.522 55.600
United Kingdom 21.000 27.750 22.000 34.750
Ukraine 6.086 76.275 16.417 74.767
Non-European countries
Algeria 0.530 99.000 49.400
Australia 0.942 71.167 8.467 51.117
India 7.100 8.100
Indonesia 1.667 92.586 4.858 80.429
Pakistan 4.000 91.433 6.500 83.867
South Africa 17.000 52.000
South Korea 4.925 85.900 4.350 80.375
Thailand 2.242 86.667 3.925 78.333
Tunisia 50.775
  • Data Source: ECB, authors’ compilation.

The role of the euro is further illustrated in Figure 11, which displays the euro invoicing share in a country's imports (exports) against the country's imports from (exports to) the Eurozone as a share of its total imports (exports). Following Goldberg and Tille (2008), all sample points would lie along the 45-degree line under the extreme case of complete euro invoicing of trade with the Eurozone and no vehicle currency role for the euro. For European countries, observations lie close to this reference line, with more than half of them lying above. In contrast, the use of the euro for trade invoicing in non-European countries is much smaller than what would be expected purely based on the direct trade flows with the Eurozone. For comparison, the role of the US dollar in trade invoicing across countries is shown in Figure 12. The use of the dollar is far more than the trade with the United States for all sampled countries. Taken together, Figures 11 and 12 imply the tipping phenomenon in the sense that the currency invoicing share is convex in the underlying conditions of the issuing country, such as economic size and trade share.

Details are in the caption following the image
Use of the Euro for Trade Invoicing Across Countries
  • Data Source: ECB, authors’ compilation.
Details are in the caption following the image
Use of the US Dollar for Trade Invoicing Across Countries
  • Data Source: authors’ compilation.

4.2.3 Regression Analysis

We focus on one specific currency, the euro, to understand its use for trade invoicing in different countries. Without variation across currencies, we cannot identify the tipping phenomenon or test the convex relationship between the invoicing share of a currency and the GDP share of its issuing country, and neither is there such a need. In this context, our empirical analysis does not directly account for thick market externalities and underlying institutional factors. In fact, we are dealing with a new question, and therefore, our model specification is different to the one used in Section 4a.

Specifically, we estimate an equation that is modified from Goldberg and Tille (2008), who derive this aggregate invoicing function based on the microfounded model:
urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0027

The dependent variable urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0028 is the share of euro invoicing in the exports or imports of country i in year t. The variable urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0029 is the share of the Eurozone in the total trade (exports and imports) of country i, urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0030 is the economic size of country i relative to the Eurozone, EU is an indicator variable for the EU membership of country i, yeareur is the number of years after the introduction of the euro, taking 1999 as the base year, and pipeur–$ is the difference in bid-ask spread between the euro and the US dollar in year t. urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0031 is the currency preference for cost hedging as defined in Goldberg and Tille (2008): for country i, it equals 1 when the euro is the preferred hedging currency for transactions, 0 when the euro and the US dollar are equally preferred for hedging and −1 when the US dollar is the preferred hedging currency. Finally, urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0032 is an i.i.d. error term.

There are a number of points to note about this specification. First, as shown in Lai and Zhou (2012), countries that trade more with the Eurozone are more willing to use the emerging euro. This is an implication of the coalescing effect and captured by the coefficient δ1 on urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0033. The interaction term urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0034 is intended to reflect the potential effect that a smaller country tends to be more reliant on trading with the Eurozone and more affected by the trade share with the Eurozone urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0035. The weak influence of its own currency, home or abroad, would give way to the euro. Therefore, we may expect the sign of the coefficient δ2 to be negative. Second, the time trend variable yeareur is included because the growth in relative economic size of the issuing country leads to the emergence of its currency as a major invoicing currency. In the case of the euro, the economic size of the Eurozone jumped immediately when the euro was introduced and increased as more and more European countries adopted the euro as their official currency. In addition, this time variable also captures the inertia in adopting the euro for invoicing purposes. By an argument similar to the above, the interaction term urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0036 allows for the potential effect that a smaller country tends to adopt the euro faster, and hence, the sign of its coefficient δ6 is expected to be negative. Finally, term pipeur–$ captures the effect of the differential in transaction costs, which are calculated in a way that is standard in literature – the median difference between the bid-ask spreads (pips) of the euro and the dollar on the local currency each year.

Table 8 presents the results for euro invoicing in exports, with the explanatory variables added one by one. The share of the Eurozone in a country's total trade urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0037 has strongly positive effect on the use of the euro in export invoicing by a country, and it contributes to explaining more than 60 per cent of the cross-country and intertemporal variation in the euro's share in export invoicing (adjusted R2 is equal to 0.601 in column (1)). This supports distinguishing countries according to their trade relationship with the Eurozone. The negative and significant coefficient on urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0038 shows that the euro is used less in exports by countries that are relatively large, when the share of trade with the Eurozone is controlled for. EU members use the euro more widely, as suggested by column (3). The hedging motive seems not as important in magnitude, but is statistically significant, according to column (4). The time trend yeareur enters with a significant and positive coefficient (column (5)). In general, the use of the euro increases over time, owing mainly to an increasing contribution of smaller countries, as signified by strongly negative coefficient on the interaction term urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0039 (column (6)). In particular, when this is introduced, the magnitude of the coefficient on the first interaction term urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0040 drops by nearly half, because these two terms are partially correlated. Consistent with Goldberg and Tille (2008), column (7) shows that pipeur–$ is insignificant in explaining invoicing currency choice. Since missing observations in the data for transaction costs limit the number of observations that we can use, we report the results without these for import invoicing and in the counterfactual analysis for the renminbi.

Table 8. Determinants of the Euro's Share in a Country's Export Invoicing
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
Eurozone's share in exporter's total trade 1.273 1.319 1.144 1.223 1.184 1.215 1.298
(0.072) (0.069) (0.078) (0.072) (0.074) (0.075) (0.076)
Eurozone’ share in exporter's total trade × ratio of exporter's size to Eurozone –3.675 –3.889 –3.356 –1.980 –1.371 –1.712
(0.759) (0.732) (0.670) (0.932) (0.979) (0.749)
EU dummy (exporter = EU member) 0.117 0.084 0.069 0.063 0.082
(0.028) (0.026) (0.026) (0.026) (0.028)
No. of years after introduction of euro 0.021 0.0249 0.025 0.031
(0.003) (0.004) (0.004) (0.003)
No. of years after introduction of euro × ratio of exporter's size to Eurozone –0.212 –0.208 –0.247
(0.101) (0.100) (0.077)
Preferred hedging currency –0.062 –0.040
(0.032) (0.032)
Diff. in bid–ask spread btw euro and USD –0.564
(1.722)
Constant –0.0348 –0.0287 –0.0271 –0.163 –0.149 –0.171 –0.224
(0.030) (0.029) (0.028) (0.032) (0.033) (0.035) (0.033)
Adjusted R-square 0.601 0.639 0.666 0.725 0.729 0.733 0.877
No. of observations 210 210 210 210 210 210 144

Notes

  • (i) Standard errors are reported in parentheses.
  • (ii) ***< 0.01, **< 0.05 and *< 0.1.
Table 9. Determinants of the Euro's Share in a Country's Import Invoicing
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
Eurozone's share in importer's total trade 1.238 1.301 1.219 1.248 1.202 1.202
(0.063) (0.058) (0.071) (0.068) (0.070) (0.071)
Eurozone’ share in importer's total trade × ratio of importer's size to Eurozone –4.190 –4.248 –3.918 –2.393 –2.394
(0.607) (0.603) (0.585) (0.812) (0.862)
EU dummy (importer = EU member) 0.048 0.0328 0.0169 0.017
(0.025) (0.024) (0.024) (0.025)
No. of years after introduction of euro 0.0116 0.0158 0.016
(0.003) (0.003) (0.003)
No. of years after introduction of euro × ratio of exporter's size to Eurozone –0.233 –0.233
(0.087) (0.087)
Preferred hedging currency 0.000
(0.028)
Constant –0.00664 –0.00218 0.00102 –0.0717 –0.056 –0.056
(0.026) (0.023) (0.023) (0.028) (0.029) (0.031)
Adjusted R-square 0.659 0.725 0.729 0.749 0.757 0.756
No. of observations 199 199 199 199 199 199

Notes

  • (i) Standard errors are reported in parentheses.
  • (ii) ***< 0.01, **< 0.05 and *< 0.1.

Table 9 reports the results for euro invoicing for imports, which share similar patterns with those for euro invoicing for exports. This is an extension of Goldberg and Tille (2008), who only examine export invoicing. Overall, both sets of our estimates are close to their findings, both qualitatively and quantitatively.

5 The Potential of the Renminbi as an Invoicing Currency

In this section, we evaluate the potential of the renminbi for trade invoicing in the Asia-Pacific region, based on the two sets of empirical evidence in Section 3.1. We continue to offer two different angles for the assessment: the extent of renminbi invoicing in the bilateral trade between Thailand and other countries and the extent of renminbi invoicing in the total trade of countries in the Asia-Pacific region.

5.1 The Implications of the Cross-currency Experience

To capture the effects of thick market externalities, our empirical analysis evaluates the impact of the normalised global FX turnover of a currency on the extent to which the currency is used as an invoicing currency in various countries of the world. In 2013, the renminbi was the 9th-most traded currency (BIS, 2013), but as shown in Table 10, its market share remained very limited, accounting for only about 1 per cent of global turnover. Relative to China's GDP share, its turnover share is even smaller (no larger than, for example, Thai baht). On the other hand, this means that the renminbi has a lot of potential in the development of its market thickness, which in turn can promote its use as an invoicing currency.

Table 10. Global FX Turnover Share and GDP Share
1998 2001 2004 2007 2010 2013
Global FX turnover share (%)
US$ 43.401 44.932 44.004 42.798 42.430 43.523
EUR 18.956 18.705 18.518 19.526 16.706
GBP 5.508 6.523 8.249 7.433 6.440 5.905
JPY 10.862 11.767 10.415 8.625 9.496 11.519
CAD 1.763 2.244 2.100 2.145 2.642 2.284
SGD 0.553 0.527 0.453 0.584 0.709 0.698
THB 0.071 0.076 0.100 0.098 0.096 0.160
RMB 0.007 0.004 0.048 0.226 0.431 1.119
Ratio of FX turnover share to GDP share
US$ 1.500 1.411 1.577 1.711 1.869 1.996
EUR 0.960 0.809 0.836 1.027 0.985
GBP 1.138 1.428 1.588 1.469 1.813 1.744
JPY 0.838 0.909 0.946 1.105 1.097 1.390
CAD 0.863 1.008 0.895 0.841 1.064 0.902
SGD 1.744 1.859 1.751 1.935 2.073 1.827
THB 0.193 0.210 0.262 0.221 0.192 0.314
RMB 0.002 0.001 0.011 0.036 0.046 0.096

Notes

  • The GDP data are not yet available for 2013 when we wrote this paper. We use 2012 GDP share as a proxy when computing the ratio of foreign exchange turnover share to GDP share in the last column of the lower panel.
  • Data Source: BIS, World Bank.

To make predictions about the potential of the renminbi, we rely on the empirical models reported in columns (3) and (4) of Table 5 for imports and exports, respectively. The estimates are based on our preferred logistic specification, which is robust across different regressor configurations. In particular, we consider two cases: (i) China is the trading partner of Thailand and (ii) an average ASEAN country is the trading partner of Thailand.

We use the 2010 data on China's share in Thailand's total trade, China's share in the partner's trade, exchange rate co-movement between the renminbi and Thai baht and renminbi exchange rate volatility. With these variables fixed at their values in 2010, we compute the required GDP share for the share of renminbi invoicing to reach certain level under different assumptions about market depth. In particular, we show how the required GDP share varies with the imposed ratio of FX turnover share to GDP share. Table 11 shows the Chinese data on the main explanatory variables in 2010, along with the US data for the same year. China is not comparable with the United States in either economic size, thickness of its currency market or capital market depth.

Table 11. Values of Main Variables for China and the United States in 2010
Main Variables China (RMB) United States (US$)
Dependent variables
Currency share in Thailand import from issuer 0.935
Currency share in Thailand export to issuer 0.945
Currency share in Thailand import from ASEAN 0.869
Currency share in Thailand export to ASEAN 0.796
Independent variables
Issuer's GDP share 0.094 0.227
Issuer's share in Thailand total trade 0.121 0.079
Issuer's share in ASEAN's total trade 0.173 0.107
Exchange rate co-movement with Baht 0.782 0.735
Exchange rate volatility 0.358 0.313
Ratio of FX turnover share to issuer's GDP share 0.046 1.869
Issuer's capital market depth 1.052 1.947
  • Data Source: Bank of Thailand, BIS, World Bank.

Table 12 presents the results for renminbi invoicing in the trade between Thailand and China. It shows that, at the current level of the renminbi's FX market thickness and China's GDP share, the renminbi could reach an invoicing share around 10 per cent in Thailand's trade with China. Although there is no direct evidence on renminbi invoicing in the Thailand–China trade, the fact that China was the second-largest trading partner of Thailand, accounting for 17 per cent of Thailand's total trade in 2010, and that the renminbi was not visible in the currency distribution Thailand's total trade (the minimum observation is less than 0.5 per cent) imply that the renminbi is still far from reaching its projected invoicing share in the bilateral trade.

Table 12. Required GDP Share of China to Achieve Given Renminbi Invoicing Share in the Thailand–China Trade
Ratio of FX Turnover Share to GDP Share
0.046 (as of 2010) 0.5 1.00 1.50
RMB invoicing share in Thailand's imports (%)
10 8.371 6.095 3.588 1.081
20 11.785 9.509 7.002 4.495
25 12.996 10.720 8.213 5.706
30 14.054 11.778 9.271 6.764
40 15.914 13.637 11.131 8.624
50 17.620 15.344 12.838 10.331
RMB invoicing share in Thailand's exports (%)
10 12.405 8.856 8.856 1.038
20 15.877 12.328 12.328 4.510
25 17.109 13.560 13.560 5.742
30 18.185 14.636 14.636 6.818
40 20.077 16.528 16.528 8.710
50 21.813 18.264 18.264 10.446

Notes

  • (i) Calculations are based on the empirical models with logistic transformation, as reported in columns (3) and (4) of Table 5.
  • (ii) It is assumed that all independent variables other than GDP share and FX turnover share will remain at their current level.

Why is the renminbi so much underused in the invoicing of trade? One possible reason is inertia in the adoption of an emerging currency. Although changes in fundamental conditions imply changes in the composition of invoicing currencies, there may be a substantial time lag in adjustment. As argued by Krugman (1984, p. 268), ‘the choice of a vehicle currency reflects both history and hysteresis’. A similar argument applies for invoicing currencies and might explain why the renminbi has not realised its potential yet. Another possible explanation is that the implied potential reflects only the average experience of different currencies, but idiosyncratic factors may contribute to the disparity between actual use and average potential.

Moreover, it clear from Table 12 that when the renminbi's market thickness increases, the required GDP share for the emergence of the renminbi as a major invoicing currency becomes significantly smaller. This shows the importance of improving capital account openness and financial development.

Table 13 reports the predictions for the potential of the renminbi as a vehicle currency in invoicing trade between Thailand and ASEAN countries. When China is not involved in the trade, it requires a much higher GDP share of China for the renminbi to play an important role than the share required when China is the trading partner. However, if the FX-share-GDP-share ratio of the renminbi reaches a level comparable to that of more established currencies (e.g. 1 or 1.5), the renminbi could have an invoicing share of around 10 per cent when China's GDP share reaches 13 to 18 per cent, which is likely to be achieved in the near future. The renminbi could even play a leading role (around 40 to 60 per cent invoicing share) in the ASEAN region as a vehicle currency was China's GDP share to reach a level around 25 per cent, which is roughly the GDP share of the United States in 2012, under the assumption of high capital account openness and financial development, and hence a thick market for the renminbi.

Table 13. Required GDP Share of China to Achieve Given Renminbi Invoicing Share in the Thailand–ASEAN Trade
Ratio of FX Turnover Share to GDP Share
0.046 (as of 2010) 0.5 1.00 1.50
RMB invoicing share in Thailand's imports (%)
10 21.541 19.265 16.758 14.251
20 24.955 22.678 20.172 17.665
25 26.166 23.890 21.383 18.876
30 27.223 24.947 22.441 19.934
40 29.083 26.807 24.301 21.794
50 30.790 28.514 26.007 23.501
RMB invoicing share in Thailand's exports (%)
10 25.032 21.483 17.574 13.665
20 28.504 24.955 21.046 17.137
25 29.736 26.186 22.277 18.368
30 30.812 27.262 23.353 19.444
40 32.703 29.154 25.245 21.336
50 34.439 30.890 26.981 23.072

Notes

  • (i) Calculations are based on the empirical models with logistic transformation, as reported in columns (3) and (4) of Table 5.
  • (ii) It is assumed that all independent variables other than GDP share and FX turnover share will remain at their current level.

5.2 The Implications of the Euro's Experience

The euro was introduced in 1999 as a new currency and offers a comparison for the path of the renminbi as an emerging currency today. The circumstances in which the euro found itself then were a bit like those in which the renminbi finds itself today, namely aspiring to be a regional currency that challenges the incumbent currency, the US dollar. We use the estimation results for the euro presented in Section 4b to predict the potential path of the renminbi in trade invoicing.

We are using the euro's experience to estimate the potential use of the renminbi for trade invoicing. By potential, we mean the invoicing share of the renminbi conditional on China reaching the same degree of capital account openness and financial development as the Eurozone, so that the renminbi has a market as thick as the euro. In carrying out the estimation, we make a couple of assumptions. First, we assume that the empirical model estimated for the euro is applicable to the renminbi. The variables included in the model should behave in the same way. For example, the share of China in the total trade of a country should have the same marginal effect on the use of the renminbi as that of the Eurozone on euro invoicing measured by the estimate of coefficient δ1. Second, there are aspects for which we cannot draw parallels between the euro and the renminbi. For example, before the launch of the euro, the German mark had been used as an invoicing currency in continental Europe to a large extent. Once the euro was introduced, those who used the German mark likely switched to the euro immediately. Thus, the share of euro invoicing in some European countries was already non-trivial at the birth of the currency (Portes and Rey, 1998). This is certainly not true for the renminbi. From this perspective, it may be useful to consider our out-of-sample predictions based on the euro regressions as an upper bound for the potential use of the renminbi in trade invoicing.

Specifically, our predictions are based on the estimates contained in column (3) of Tables 8 and 9 for export and import invoicing, respectively. This is because of there is no China-equivalent for yeareur, years after the introduction of the euro. It is still hard to assess the international use of the renminbi for cost hedging. There is thus no China-equivalent for urn:x-wiley:03785920:media:twec12211:twec12211-math-0041 either, the indicator for the euro as preferred hedging currency over the US dollar. Columns (3) account for the effect of EU membership. The equivalent ‘China-dummy’ should be set to zero for all countries that we are considering. The actual Chinese data on all other variables are used to pin down the implied invoicing shares of the renminbi.

The results for both export invoicing and import invoicing are listed in Table 14. For example, based on the data of 2010, potential renminbi invoicing in Australia, Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia, Philippines and Singapore is in the range of between 8 and 12 per cent of the country's total imports or exports, assuming the same level of capital account openness and financial development as the Eurozone. The implied potential use of the renminbi increases from 2008 to 2010, reflecting the growth in relative economic size of China in the global economy.

Table 14. Potential Invoicing Share of the Renminbi in the Trade of Some Asia-Pacific Countries, Based on Projection from the Euro's Experience
Export Import
2008 Data 2010 Data 2008 Data 2010 Data
Australia 3.8 8.3 3.6 8.5
Indonesia 7.1 8.2 7.4 8.6
Korea 6.7 10.2 6.7 10.5
Malaysia 10.3 12.6 10.9 13.4
Philippines 9.2 9.9 9.8 10.6
Singapore 9.8 10.7 10.4 11.3
Thailand 9.1 11.1 9.6 11.7

Notes

  • (i) Calculations are based on the empirical models reported in Column (3) of Tables 8 and 9.
  • (ii) The projections using the 2008 and 2010 data of China-equivalent of the independent variables are reported.

We present the predictions for Thailand (the last row of Table 14) to enable an indirect comparison with the results obtained from the Thailand data (Tables 12 and 13). Suppose that the FX-share-GDP-share ratio of the renminbi reached that of the euro, of 1.03 in 2010 (Table 10). Given that China's GDP share is 9.4 per cent in 2010 and that the shares of China and ASEAN countries in Thailand's total imports are 13.3 and 16.6 per cent, respectively, the potential invoicing share of the renminbi in Thailand's imports from China+ASEAN is 14.9 per cent, based on the cross-currency regression analysis for Thailand. Only a smaller renminbi invoicing share in Thailand's imports from the rest of the world, which cannot be directly estimated using this approach, is needed to reach the aggregate renminbi invoicing share of 11.7 per cent as stated in Table 14. In the light of the geo-economic factors, this is reasonable. A similar calculation follows for export invoicing. Therefore, our two sets of counterfactual predictions are consistent, or at least compatible, with each other, although we cannot directly compare the two sets of numbers.

As argued above, the assessment given in Table 14 should be treated as an upper bound for the potential of the renminbi as an invoicing currency as there are a number of factors favourable to the euro's use as an invoicing currency when it was launched not shared by the renminbi.

6 Conclusion

Trade invoicing reflects the function of an international currency as a unit of account. In this paper, we develop a simple model to show that the coalescing effect and thick market externalities lead to a convex relationship between the invoicing share of a currency and the economic size of its issuing country, which we call the ‘tipping phenomenon’ of trade invoicing. Constrained by the availability of the data, there is sparse evidence on invoicing behaviour. This paper contributes to the literature by providing new evidence on the determinants of the use of a currency in trade invoicing. Our empirical analysis provides evidence for the tipping phenomenon and the underlying role of thick market externalities, as proxied by the ratio of the FX turnover share of the currency to the GDP share of the issuing country. We argue that to arrive at this ‘tipping point’, the issuing country has to establish a sufficiently thick market for its currency.

Applying the empirical models to evaluate the potential of the renminbi, our quantitative thought experiments suggest that there is large scope for the use of the renminbi in trade invoicing in the Asia-Pacific region and beyond. We argue that China needs to have a more open capital account and a more liberalised financial sector to achieve the required thick market externalities for the renminbi to emerge as a major invoicing currency. Market-driven invoicing behaviour may exhibit a good deal of inertia, but transformations of the global economic landscape will induce changes in the international currency system eventually. As China's relative economic size increases, capital controls are gradually relaxed, and financial reforms are gradually implemented, it seems inevitable that the renminbi will become a major invoicing currency in the Asia-Pacific region. The only question is when.

Notes

  • 1 Before 2013, the General Administration of Customs of China released official statistics on imports and exports only in terms of the US dollar, but not in China's own currency (except for annual data published in the China Customs Statistics Yearbooks).
  • 2 Ito and Chinn (2013) take a similar approach to study the potential of renminbi invoicing and the role of capital account liberalisation in China.
  • 3 A vehicle currency is defined as a currency used for invoicing trade when the issuing country is not one of the trading partners.
  • 4 That said, the OLS estimates represent important baseline results, not only in illustrating the marginal effects of regressors on the invoicing share, but also in spelling out the intuition behind the tipping phenomenon.
  • 5 Cyprus, Estonia, Latvia, Slovakia and Slovenia adopted the euro as the official currency during 2007–14. We repeat our test by adjusting for this and find the results almost unchanged.
  • 6 Our data set covers the data of Goldberg and Tille (2008) as a subset. There are only 24 countries for which they have invoicing information, with the latest observations being around 2003. For the details of data sources, please refer to Goldberg and Tille (2005) and Kamps (2006).
  • 7 However, when we repeat our analysis with it, the results are almost unaltered. For example, for import invoicing, the estimates on other variables are very close to those presented in column (7) of Table 9.
  • 8 Yet another possible reason is that the effect of the FX-share-to-GDP-share ratio on the left-hand-side variable is non-linear (i.e. convex). In that case, we overestimate the potential of the renminbi when the ratio is small, but underestimate it when the ratio is large.
  • Appendix A: Description of the Thailand Data

    A1 Variables and Data Sources

    In this section, we give detailed definition of the variables used in Section 4a and provide information on data sources.

    Dependent Variables

    Currency invoicing share in Thailand exports to partner country: the share of exports using the specified currency as receipts in the total exports from Thailand to the specified partner country. Source: Bank of Thailand.

    Currency invoicing share in Thailand imports from partner country: the share of imports using the specified currency as payment in the total imports to Thailand from the specified partner country. Source: Bank of Thailand.

    The share is calculated from trade values in the US dollar. For the euro, whose history begins in 1999, the invoicing share is unobservable before 1999. Similarly, for the German mark, French franc and Italian lira, the invoicing share is unobservable after 2002.

    Independent Variables

    Issuer's GDP share: the ratio of the currency issuing country's GDP to the world GDP in a given year. All GDP are evaluated at market exchange rates. Source: World Bank.

    Issuer's share in Thailand total trade: the share of Thailand's trade (imports + exports) with the currency issuing country in the total trade of Thailand with the rest of the world, evaluated in the US dollar. Since the issuing country of the Thai baht is Thailand itself, the share is then normalised to be 1. Source: Bank of Thailand.

    Issuer's share in partner's total trade: the share of the currency issuing country's trade with the partner country in the total trade of the partner country with the rest of the world. All trade values are in the US dollar. If the partner country and the currency issuing country are the same, the share is normalised to be 1. Source: UN Comtrade.

    EX co-movement with THB: measured as the correlation coefficients between the exchange rate of Thai baht against Swiss franc and exchange rate of invoicing currency against Swiss franc. For Thai baht, EX co-movement with THB is always 1. Source: Bloomberg.

    EX co-movement with partner's currency: measured as the correlation coefficient between the exchange rate of the partner country against the Swiss franc and exchange rate of invoicing currency against the Swiss franc. If partner country's currency is the invoicing currency, EX co-movement with partner's currency is 1. Source: Bloomberg.

    EX volatility: standard deviation of daily percentage change of the exchange rate of invoicing currency against the SDR. Source: Bloomberg.

    EX bid-ask spread: measured as the ratio of the difference between bid and ask exchange rates to the average of bid and ask rates of the invoicing currency against the Thai baht. All bid and ask prices are monthly end data. The bid-ask spread is 0 for the Thai baht. Source: Bank of Thailand.

    FX turnover share: the share of the transactions involving the invoicing currency in total FX turnover of the world. The data for 1998, 2001, 2004, 2007 and 2010 are available from the Bank of International Settlements. For other years between 1998 and 2010, the FX turnover share is interpolated using the log-linear model. Source: Bank of International Settlements.

    Issuer's capital market depth: the ratio of stock market capitalisation plus outstanding domestic private debt securities to GDP of the currency issuing country. Source: World Bank.

    A2 Descriptive Statistics

    To provide more information on the structure of the Thailand data, Tables A1–A3 contain descriptive statistics on currencies, trading partners and variables.

    Table A1. Some Statistics about the Currencies in the Thailand Data
    Currency No. of observations Percentage of Total Currency No. of observations Percentage of Total
    US$ 505 24.12 SGD 119 5.68
    THB 486 23.21 FRF 62 2.96
    GBP 231 11.03 MYR 60 2.87
    JPY 208 9.93 ITL 33 1.58
    EUR 194 9.26 CAD 25 1.19
    DEM 171 8.17
    Table A2. Some Statistics about Trading Partners in the Thailand Data
    Partner No. of observations Percentage of Total Partner No. of observations Percentage of Total
    Austria 75 3.58 Laos 38 1.81
    Belgium 89 4.25 Luxembourg 67 3.2
    Brunei Darussalam 77 3.68 Malaysia 95 4.54
    Cambodia 43 2.05 Mexico 49 2.34
    Canada 72 3.44 Myanmar 62 2.96
    Denmark 81 3.87 Netherlands 88 4.2
    Finland 75 3.58 Philippines 77 3.68
    France 85 4.06 Portugal 73 3.49
    Germany 91 4.35 Singapore 90 4.3
    Greece 73 3.49 Spain 95 4.54
    Indonesia 81 3.87 Sweden 77 3.68
    Ireland 86 4.11 United Kingdom 93 4.44
    Italy 95 4.54 United States 62 2.96
    Japan 57 2.72 Vietnam 48 2.29
    Table A3. Descriptive Statistics for the Thailand Data
    Variable Mean Standard Deviation Min Max No. of observations
    Dependent variable
    Invoicing share in import 0.255 0.327 0.001 1.000 1901
    Invoicing share in export 0.271 0.350 0.001 1.000 1821
    Independent variable
    Issuer's GDP share 0.110 0.109 0.002 0.318 2094
    Issuer's share in Thailand total trade 0.300 0.389 0.006 1.000 2094
    Issuer's share in partner's total trade 0.174 0.266 0.000 1.000 1918
    EX co-movement with THB 0.667 0.366 −0.473 1.000 2076
    EX co-movement with partner's currency 0.676 0.397 −0.822 1.000 1599
    EX volatility 0.529 0.258 0.193 1.848 2094
    EX bid-ask spread 0.011 0.010 0.000 0.081 2011
    Ratio of FX turnover share to GDP share 1.058 0.635 0.079 2.285 1488
    Issuer's capital market depth 1.325 0.656 0.322 3.030 2094
    Year 1993 2011

    Appendix B: Description of the Euro Data

    B1 Variables and Data Sources

    We provide more details on the definition of the variables and the source of the data used in Section 4b below.

    Dependent Variables

    EUR's share in export invoicing of a country: the share of exports using the euro as receipts in the total exports of the specified country. Source: ECB, central banks of individual countries.

    EUR's share in import invoicing of a country: the share of imports using the euro as payment in the total imports of the specified country. Source: ECB, central banks of individual countries.

    The shares are calculated from trade values in the US dollar if not directly available from the original source.

    Independent Variables

    Eurozone's share in country's total export: the share of the country's exports to the Eurozone in the country's total exports to the rest of the world, evaluated in the US dollar. Source: WTO.

    Eurozone's share in country's total import: the share of the country's imports from the Eurozone in the country's total imports from the rest of the world, evaluated in the US dollar. Source: WTO.

    Ratio of country's GDP to Eurozone's GDP: the ratio of the specified country's GDP to the aggregated GDP of the Eurozone in a given year. All GDP are evaluated at market exchange rates. Source: World Bank.

    EUR as preferred hedging currency: a dummy variable, with variable equals 1 when the euro is the preferred hedging currency for transactions and 0 otherwise. A preferred hedging currency is defined in Goldberg and Tille (2008). Source: Goldberg and Tille (2008).

    EU dummy: an indicator variable for the EU membership of a country. It equals 1 when the country is a member of EU and 0 otherwise. Source: authors’ compilation.

    Number of years after introduction of EUR: the number of years after the introduction of the euro. Source: authors’ compilation.

    Bid-ask spread against EUR: the ratio of the difference between bid and ask exchange rates to the average of bid and ask rates of the country's currency against the euro. All bid and ask prices are monthly end data. Source: Bloomberg.

    Bid-ask spread against USD: the ratio of the difference between bid and ask exchange rates to the average of bid and ask rates of the country's currency against the US dollar. All bid and ask prices are monthly end data. Source: Bloomberg.

    B2 Descriptive Statistics

    As indicated in Section 4b, the euro data set covers 35 countries from 1999 to 2010. The panel is not balanced. Table B1 contains more information on observations by country.

    Table B1. Some Statistics about Countries in the Euro Data
    Country No. of observations Percentage of Total Country No. of observations Percentage of Total
    Algeria 2 0.67 Luxembourg 11 3.68
    Australia 12 4.01 Macedonia, FYR 12 4.01
    Belgium 10 3.34 Netherlands 5 1.67
    Bulgaria 13 4.35 Pakistan 3 1.00
    Croatia 12 4.01 Poland 12 4.01
    Cyprus 4 1.34 Portugal 11 3.68
    Czech Republic 12 4.01 Romania 12 4.01
    Denmark 6 2.01 Slovakia 8 2.68
    Estonia 8 2.68 Slovenia 10 3.34
    France 12 4.01 South Africa 1 0.33
    Germany 6 2.01 South Korea 4 1.34
    Greece 10 3.34 Spain 13 4.35
    Hungary 7 2.34 Thailand 12 4.01
    India 1 0.33 Tunisia 4 1.34
    Indonesia 12 4.01 Turkey 9 3.01
    Italy 11 3.68 United Kingdom 4 1.34
    Latvia 11 3.68 Ukraine 7 2.34
    Lithuania 12 4.01

    Table B2 provides a set of descriptive statistics on the variables used for the regression analysis in Section 4b.

    Table B2. Descriptive Statistics for the Euro Data
    Variable Mean Standard Deviation Min Max No. of observations
    Dependent variables
    EUR's share in export invoicing 0.474 0.251 0.000 0.965 299
    EUR's share in import invoicing 0.461 0.224 0.017 0.833 288
    Independent variables
    Eurozone's share in country's total exports 0.434 0.190 0.037 0.783 299
    Eurozone's share in country's total imports 0.426 0.177 0.062 0.881 299
    Ratio of country's GDP to Eurozone's GDP 0.043 0.067 0.001 0.293 299
    EUR as preferred hedging currency 0.064 0.244 0.000 1.000 299
    Bid-ask spread against EUR 0.001 0.004 0.056 0.017 240
    Bid-ask spread against USD 0.001 0.003 0.000 0.032 262
    Year 1998 2010 299

      The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.