Volume 18, Issue 4 pp. 487-510
Article
Full Access

Taxing the Financially Integrated Multinational Firm

NIELS JOHANNESEN

NIELS JOHANNESEN

Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen

Search for more papers by this author
First published: 22 May 2016
Citations: 5

I would like to thank Peter Birch Sørensen and Marko Koethenbuerger for valuable comments and suggestions. I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Danish Council for Independent Research.

Abstract

This paper develops a theoretical model of corporate taxation in the presence of financially integrated multinational firms. Under the assumption that multinational firms use some measure of internal loans to finance foreign investment, we find that the optimal corporate tax rate is positive from the perspective of a small, open economy. This finding contrasts the standard result that the optimal-source-based capital tax is zero. Intuitively, when multinational firms finance investment in one country with loans from affiliates in another country, the burden of the corporate taxes levied in the latter country partly falls on investment and thus workers in the former country. This tax exporting mechanism introduces a scope for corporate taxes, which is not present in standard models of international taxation. Accounting for the internal capital markets of multinational firms thus helps resolve the tension between standard theory predicting zero capital taxes and the casual observation that countries tend to employ corporate taxes at fairly high rates.

1. Introduction

At the heart of the multinational firm is the internal capital market that allocates funds inside the firm. Affiliates of multinational firms typically finance investment with a combination of funds from external sources such as bank loans and bond emissions and funds from internal sources such as equity injections and loans from related entities. The internal capital market thus creates financial linkages within the multinational firm in the sense that affiliates are tied together by internal loans and equity stakes. The multinational firm is financially integrated.

The MiDi data set collected by the German Central Bank and recently made available for research provides a unique opportunity to assess the nature and size of these financial linkages within the multinational firm. A remarkable feature highlighted by this data set is the prevalence of internal loans. Buettner and Wamser (2013) report that foreign affiliates of German firms have an average total debt-asset ratio of around 0.60, which breaks down into an external debt-asset ratio of 0.35 and an internal debt-asset ratio of 0.25. This suggests that internal loans represent a source of financing that is quantitatively almost as important as external loans. The internal debt-asset ratio further breaks down into a parent debt-asset ratio of 0.15 and an other affiliate debt-asset ratio of 0.10. This suggests that parents as well as other affiliates are important lenders in the internal capital markets of multinational firms.

The main contribution of this paper is to show that financial linkages within multinational firms have important implications for optimal taxation of capital. The paper develops a model of corporate taxation in the presence of financially integrated multinational firms while assuming that foreign investment of multinational firms is financed with some measure of internal loans and that these internal loans are not exclusively motivated by profit shifting. These assumptions find strong support in the empirical facts about German firms documented in the MiDi data set. Not only do foreign affiliates of German firms receive around one quarter of their capital in the form of loans from related entities, but most of these loans derive from affiliates in high-tax countries: Buettner and Wamser (2013) report that around half of the internal loans derive from the parent in Germany where the corporate tax rate has consistently been very high by international standards, while Ruf and Weichenrieder (2012) report that the other half mostly derive from affiliates in high-tax countries (e.g., the United States and the United Kingdom) and only to a much smaller extent from affiliates in low-tax havens (e.g., Cayman Islands, Ireland, Switzerland, and Luxembourg). To the extent that internal lending was predominantly driven by profit shifting, we should observe internal loans flowing from low-tax countries to high-tax countries; however, we actually observe most internal loans flowing out of high-tax countries. This pattern is not inconsistent with the large body of literature finding that the financial structure of multinational firms is tax-sensitive, but it certainly seems to imply that other considerations than profit shifting play an important role in determining flows of capital within the multinational firm.

The main finding of the paper is that internal loans serving other purposes than profit shifting introduce a tax exporting mechanism that causes the optimal corporate tax rate to be positive from the perspective of a small, open economy. This contrasts with the standard result that the optimal tax on investment is zero (Gordon 1986). Intuitively, small, open economies are facing a perfectly elastic supply of capital; hence, any tax that raises the cost of investment is fully shifted to the workers. In the standard model with only domestic firms, this implies that corporate taxes are strictly dominated by labor taxes because they distort the labor supply to the same extent as labor taxes and add a distortion of the capital–labor ratio. In our model, multinational firms partly finance investment with loans from foreign affiliates. This is effectively shifting the tax base from the country of the investing affiliate to the countries of the lending affiliates because interest payments are deductible in the former country and taxable in the latter. To the extent that corporate taxes fall on interest income from loans to foreign affiliates, they raise the cost of investing in foreign countries and are therefore borne by foreign workers. This provides a tax exporting motive for using corporate taxes, which is absent in the standard model.

Returning to the internal capital markets of German firms discussed above, the paper essentially argues that the interest income generated by loans from German parents to foreign affiliates represents a tax base to which Germany should optimally apply a positive tax rate. Intuitively, taxing income that derives from loans to foreign entities has no impact on the cost of investing in the taxing country itself but generates revenue by adding to the cost of investing in foreign countries. The first-best tax system thus combines a zero tax rate on income from domestic investment as in the standard model with a positive tax on income deriving from loans to foreign affiliates. In a standard corporate tax system where a uniform tax rate applies to all corporate income, however, the optimal corporate tax rate is strictly positive and balances the benefits of taxing corporations in terms of tax exporting and the costs of taxing them in terms of a distorted capital–labor ratio.

The paper relates to several strands of literature. First, a few existing papers describe other tax exporting mechanisms. Gordon (1992) shows that when countries apply the credit principle to the taxation of foreign source income, capital taxes in the source country have no bearing on the total tax burden on investment but erode the tax revenue of the home country. Huizinga and Nielsen (1997) show that source taxes on the normal return to capital are partly shifted to foreign owners of domestic firms through a reduction in economic rents. The present paper adds to this literature by exposing a novel tax exporting mechanism whereby capital taxes are partly shifted to foreign workers through a reduction in foreign wages.

Second, a series of papers analyzes capital taxation in the presence of financially integrated multinational firms while focusing exclusively on financial strategies that allow multinational firms to shift the corporate tax base between jurisdictions. Huizinga, Laeven, and Nicodeme (2008) present a model of debt shifting where a disproportionate share of the external debt of multinationals is allocated to affiliates in high-tax countries in order to increase the tax value of the debt. A number of papers including Mintz and Smart (2004), Fuest and Hemmelgarn (2005), and Johannesen (2012) develop models of profit shifting where tax haven affiliates finance other affiliates with internal loans. Generally, the use of tax-motivated financial strategies like debt shifting and profit shifting tends to increase the tax sensitivity of capital tax bases and reinforce the race-to-the-bottom in capital tax rates. The present paper shows that the use of nontax-motivated financial strategies can also contribute to just the opposite result.

Third, a few recent papers study the interaction between internal loans and corporate tax policy in the form of thin capitalization rules, which are tax provisions limiting the deductibility of interest payments on internal loans with the aim of curbing profit shifting. Buettner et al. (2012) show empirically that thin capitalization rules significantly reduce the extent to which multinational firms rely on internal lending. Haufler and Runkel (2012) demonstrate theoretically how lax thin capitalization rules can serve as a tax competition device targeted at internationally mobile capital and how a coordinated tightening of thin capitalization rules can yield positive welfare effects.

Finally, a number of papers address the fundamental question why countries raise considerable revenue with source-based capital taxes. Gordon and Varian (1989) show that country-specific productivity shocks resurrect the case for positive capital taxes because the desire of foreign investors to hedge risk implies that the demand for domestic capital is imperfectly elastic with respect to the net-of-tax return; Gordon and MacKie-Mason (1994) argue that income shifting between different tax bases introduces a scope for using a capital income tax since the latter works as a back-stop for the personal income tax; Haufler and Wooton (1999) find that trade costs can give rise to location-specific rents that countries optimally appropriate by means of source-based capital taxes; Wildasin (2003) shows that under imperfect capital mobility, optimal capital taxes are positive and inversely related to the speed with which the capital stock adjusts in response to changes in the local return to capital; Fuest and Huber (2002) find that the optimal source tax is positive if other countries apply the credit or deduction principle to the taxation of foreign source income due to the tax exporting mechanism discussed by Gordon (1992). The present paper contributes to this literature by exploring a novel explanation for the fact that most countries levy corporate taxes at fairly high rates. Our theory is similar to Fuest and Huber (2002) in assigning a key role to the multinational firm, but the mechanism driving the result is clearly distinct in the two models.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2. develops the model framework. Section 3. derives the baseline results on optimal capital taxation in the presence of financially integrated multinational firms. Section 4. extends the results to a model where firms' financial structure is endogenous and responsive to taxation. Section 5. extends the results to a setting where financially integrated multinational firms coexist with purely domestic firms. Section 6. provides some concluding remarks.

2. The Baseline Model

We consider a world economy with a large number of small countries. Each country is inhabited by a single representative agent endowed with urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0001 units of capital and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0002 units of labor. We adopt the standard assumptions that capital is perfectly mobile across countries, whereas labor is immobile. Because of the countries' smallness, policy decisions in individual countries have a negligible impact on the required return to capital r that is determined on international capital markets. The preferences of the representative agent are represented by the utility function urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0003 where C is private consumption, X is leisure, and G is public expenditure. The utility function is assumed to be separable in consumption and leisure on the one hand and public expenditure on the other hand, urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0004, which implies that the choice between consumption and leisure is independent of the level of public expenditure. We let L denote labor supply and thus establish the following identity: urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0005. Firms produce according to the standard production function urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0006with constant returns to scale where K denotes the capital. There is free entry of firms and firms therefore earn zero profits in equilibrium.

Governments are benevolent and have access to two tax instruments: a labor tax urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0007 and a capital tax urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0008. For expositional simplicity, we assume that taxes fall directly on production factors and not on the income they generate. The tax base of the labor tax is thus L. The tax base of the capital tax is the stock of capital invested in the country K reduced by financial liabilities (the analog of deductible interest expenses) and augmented by financial assets (the analog of taxable interest income). Since firms earn no pure profits, the capital tax is equivalent to a standard corporate tax on profits net of labor costs and interest expenses. We adopt the standard assumption that governments are unable to enforce taxes on the capital income of households, for instance, due to imperfect information about foreign assets. We also assume that profits of foreign subsidiaries are tax-exempt (the territoriality principle).

The main departure from the standard model of international taxation is the assumption that producing entities are affiliates of multinational firms, which implies that they receive capital from a number of different sources. Specifically, for a producing entity in country i we define urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0009 as the fraction of its capital that is injected by affiliates in the form of equity; urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0010 as the fraction that is borrowed in external capital markets; urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0011 as the fraction that is borrowed from affiliates in the same country; and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0012 as the fraction that is borrowed from foreign affiliates in country j. We allow firms to be heterogenous along several dimensions: they may differ by the number of countries in which they operate as well as by the allocation of productive capacity between these countries. Our framework thus allows firms to be “home-biased” in the sense that the scale of production is larger at the parent entity than at foreign affiliates and economic integration to be “regional” in the sense that firms in a given country only have foreign affiliates in one or few partner countries. The only symmetry that we need to impose is that all producing entities in a given country have the same financial structure: the same share of equity, the same share of external debt, and the same distribution of internal debt across foreign counterpart countries.

Arguably, our most important assumption is that internal cross-border lending, while possibly sensitive to taxation, is not entirely driven by profit shifting so that intrafirm loans may to some extent flow from a country i to a country j where the tax rate is lower. In Section 1., we argued that this assumption is consistent with the basic patterns in the data on multinational firms' capital structure. In the following, we will briefly review the various explanations offered by the literature for the fact that the financial structure of multinational firms is typically not tax minimizing. First, Desai et al. (2004) show empirically that multinational firms extend more internal loans to foreign subsidiaries in countries with weak creditor rights where the cost of external loans tends to be higher. This suggests that the choice between internal and external financing is influenced not only by tax factors but also by the quality of external capital markets. Second, drawing on the principal-agency framework of Jensen (1986), several authors suggest that if local managers are concerned with the size of the specific subsidiary that they operate whereas the objectives of the central management relate to the performance of the global firm, debt financing represents an instrument to prevent excessive growth in subsidiaries with a large cash flow (e.g., Huizinga et al. 2008). Such considerations clearly influence the choice between internal and external sources of financing but could also have a bearing on the choice between internal debt and equity to the extent that interest payments specified ex ante represent a harder claim on subsidiary profits than dividend payments decided ex post on the basis of available accounting profits. Third, Chowdry and Coval (1998) show theoretically that with uncertainty about future earnings a high-tax parent company optimally finances a low-tax foreign subsidiary with some measure of internal loans since in some states of the world the interest income at the level of the parent company is shielded by losses. Fourth, Dischinger, Knoll, and Riedel (2014) discuss the possibility that the well-known notion of rent sharing between firm owners and workers may induce the central management to finance operating subsidiaries with internal debt rather than equity in order to erode accounting profits and mitigate wage pressure. Finally, it should be noted that internal loans constitute a much more flexible way to transfer funds within the firm than equity from a corporate law perspective, which may also explain why firms in some cases rely on loans for internal financing even when associated with a tax cost relative to equity.

Another important assumption is that governments cannot impose taxation on household savings income. The difficulties related to enforcement of capital taxes on households in the country where they reside are well known and the assumption that capital income is untaxed at the household level is standard in the tax competition literature. The main issue is offshore tax evasion: if households hold savings through foreign custodian banks, it is very hard for tax authorities to detect and tax the corresponding capital income. Yet, one may wonder whether our main result would still hold if we were to assume that taxes on household savings were enforceable? In the present framework where savings are exogenous, this would give governments a nondistortionary tax instrument; hence, the use of the corporate tax would only be optimal if its tax exporting effects were strong enough to outweigh its distortionary effects. However, a fully satisfactory answer to the question would necessitate a more elaborate modeling of the household savings decision, which is outside the scope of this paper.

3. Optimal Taxation in the Baseline Model

In this section, we assume that all firms are financially integrated multinational firms with a fixed financial structure. This facilitates the exposition of the role of financial linkages in shaping tax policy by allowing us to treat the financial structure urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0013 as a set of constant parameters and to abstract from purely domestic firms. As noted in Section 1., there is strong empirical evidence that the financial structure of multinational firms is tax-sensitive. In the next section, we therefore analyze an extended model where firms optimally choose the financial structure given the tax environment. Moreover, a significant share of the revenue from corporate taxation derives from domestic firms with no financial ties to foreign entities. In the following section, we therefore develop a two-sector model where financially integrated multinational firms coexist with domestic firms.

3.1. Capital and Labor Market Equilibrium

We first consider the profit maximization problem of a multinational firm that operates in a set of countries denoted by N. Under the assumption of a fixed financial structure, the firm maximizes profits with respect to labor and capital inputs in these countries:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0014
where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0015 denotes the effective tax rate on capital in country i, which is given by
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0016(1)
The effective tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0017 gives the global tax burden associated with investment in country i given the parameters of the financial structure. The first term reflects taxes on equity at the level of the producing entity. The last terms represent taxes on debt claims at the level of the lending affiliates. It is useful to note already at this stage that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0018 depends on capital tax rates in country i as well as all the countries from which internal loans flow into country i. Specifically, a fraction urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0019 of the capital invested in country i is taxed in country i, whereas a fraction urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0020 of the capital invested in country i is taxed in country urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0021 . The fact that operating entities in country i are partly financed with loans from affiliates in country j thus implies that countries i and j effectively share the capital tax base generated by capital investment in country i. This is at the heart of the tax exporting mechanism. A fraction urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0022 of the capital stock is effectively untaxed. This corresponds to the usual tax advantage of external debt financing when interest expenses are deductible from the corporate tax base and the corresponding interest income is not effectively taxed at the investor level.
We define the capital–labor ratio urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0023 and the function urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0024. Using these definitions and the assumption of constant returns to scale in the production technology, we restate the profit maximization problem of the firm in the following way:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0025
The first-order conditions for profit maximization with respect to urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0026 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0027 read
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0028(2)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0029(3)
Equation (2) implicitly defines the optimal capital-labor ratio urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0030 as a decreasing function of the cost of capital urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0031 and may thus be interpreted as a capital demand function. Equation (3) defines the equilibrium wage rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0032 for a given optimal capital-labor ratio and cost of capital:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0033(4)
It is easy to see that any wage rate higher (lower) than urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0034 would induce firms to contract (expand) the scale of their operations infinitely; hence, urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0035 is the unique wage rate compatible with equilibrium. Equation (4) may thus be interpreted as (the inverse of) the labor demand function.
The representative agent in country i maximizes utility under the budget constraint (stated hereunder) by choosing the optimal labor supply given the wage rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0036, the tax rate on labor urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0037, and nonlabor income urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0038.
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0039(5)
The first-order condition states:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0040(6)
Equation 6 implicitly determines the labor supply urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0041. We impose throughout the paper that the labor supply is positively related to the net-of-tax wage urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0042. The equilibrium capital stock urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0043 follows directly from urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0044 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0045.

Summing up, Equations 2, 4, 5, and 6 define the equilibrium economic outcomes (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0046) in country i conditional on the tax policy variables and the world return to capital r. Note that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0047 is decreasing in the return to capital (in fact, both urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0048 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0049 are decreasing in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0050—the latter through the equilibrium wage urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0051).

3.2. Tax Policy

We now turn to the determination of optimal policy in country i. The government maximizes urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0052 while correctly anticipating how capital and labor market outcomes respond to taxes. Public expenditure is given by the following expression:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0053(7)
It should be noted that the last term of urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0054 represents a link between government revenue in country i and investment in other countries since the tax base in country i includes loans granted by entities in country i to affiliates in other countries.
To ease comparison with previous work, we first consider the special case where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0055 corresponding to the assumptions of the standard model where firms are completely equity-financed. In this special case, we have urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0056 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0057; hence, there are no intrafirm financial linkages and the scope for tax exporting is effectively eliminated. Inserting 5 and 7 into the utility function, we can derive the following first-order conditions for utility maximization with respect to the labor tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0058 and the capital tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0059, respectively (see Appendix):
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0060(8)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0061(9)
where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0062 is the elasticity of the labor supply urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0063 with respect to the labor tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0064 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0065 is the elasticity of the capital–labor ratio urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0066 with respect to the effective capital tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0067, which in this special case equals urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0068. It is easy to see that 8 and 9 require that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0069, which only holds when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0070. We summarize this result in the following proposition:

PROPOSITION 1.When operating subsidiaries are fully equity-financed urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0071, the optimal tax rate on capital is zero.

This proposition restates the result derived by Gordon (1986) as a special case where firms are fully equity-financed. It is instructive to inspect the first-order conditions in more detail. The expressions in curly brackets in (8 ) and 9 capture the inverse marginal cost of public funds for each of the two tax instruments, which is the amount of public revenue raised with the labor tax and the capital tax, respectively, for each unit of private consumption foregone. For urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0072, the marginal deadweight loss has two terms, both related to labor supply responses and thus proportional to the tax elasticity of the labor supply. The first term urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0073 represents changes in the labor tax revenue, whereas the second term urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0074 represents changes in the capital tax revenue. The latter effect owes itself to the fact that changes in the labor supply urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0075 produce proportional changes in the capital tax base urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0076 for a given capital–labor ratio urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0077. For urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0078, the marginal deadweight loss has the same two terms and an additional term urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0079. The first two terms reflect that capital taxes reduce the net-of-tax wage urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0080 by exactly the same amount as labor taxes per dollar of revenue raised where capital taxes work through changes in the gross wage rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0081. The third term captures the distortion of the capital-labor ratio introduced by the capital tax. It follows directly that labor taxes raise more revenue than capital taxes per unit of private consumption foregone and that capital taxes should therefore not be employed. In brief, capital taxes distort the labor supply to the same extent as labor taxes, and moreover distort the capital–labor ratio of firms; hence, they are inferior to labor taxes.

We now turn to the more general case where operating subsidiaries are financed with a mix of equity, external loans, and internal loans. Inserting 5 and 7 into the utility function, we can show that the first-order conditions for utility maximization with respect to the labor tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0082 and the capital tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0083 are (see Appendix)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0084(10)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0085(11)

As before, the expressions in curly brackets express the inverse marginal cost of public funds. For urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0086, the marginal cost of public funds is identical to the case of fully equity-financed firms except for the factor urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0087 on the last term, which reflects that behavioral responses reducing the capital stock urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0088 now have a smaller revenue effect since only a fraction urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0089 of it is effectively taxed in country i. For urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0090, the marginal cost of public funds includes the same terms as for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0091 and four additional terms. We consider these terms in turn. The first term urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0092 is the equivalent of the last term inside the curly brackets in equation 9 and captures the marginal deadweight loss associated with distortions of the capital–labor ratio urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0093. The second term urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0094 is the tax exporting effect, which reflects that capital taxes in country i are partly borne by workers in country j. Intuitively, the tax exporting effect is increasing in the foreign capital stock effectively subject to domestic capital taxation urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0095 and decreasing in the domestic capital stock effectively subject to domestic capital taxation urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0096. The final two terms capture behavioral responses in country j that erode capital tax revenues in country i. Intuitively, capital taxes in country i raise effective capital taxation in country j and thus lower the capital stock, which is partly subject to taxation in country i, through reductions in both urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0097 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0098.

Equations 10 and 11 imply that an optimal tax mix in country i must satisfy the following equation:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0099(12)
It is easy to verify that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0100 is positive, whereas all other terms are proportional to and have the opposite sign as urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0101 (see Appendix). It follows that only a tax vector urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0102 with urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0103 can satisfy Equations 10 and 11. We summarize this result in the following proposition:

PROPOSITION 2.When operating subsidiaries have a fixed financial structure with some cross-border internal loans urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0104, the optimal capital tax rate is strictly positive.

The result reported in Proposition 2 is driven by tax exporting. Capital taxes in country i raise the cost of capital in both countries i and j and part of the tax burden is therefore borne by workers in country j through a reduction in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0105. Capital taxes still have the undesirable effect of distorting the capital–labor ratio; however, the marginal deadweight loss is second-order when evaluated at the undistorted starting point urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0106. It follows that the optimal capital tax rate is positive.

It should be noted that Proposition 2 does not characterize the equilibrium capital tax rate but conveys the stronger finding that country i optimally chooses a positive capital tax rate regardless of the tax policies chosen by country j.

4. Endogenous Financial Structure

The purpose of this section is to show that the main result presented in Proposition 2 holds when the financial structure of the multinational firm responds to changes in the tax environment. We do not explicitly model the multitude of determinants of the optimal financial structure, but adopt a reduced-form specification. It is assumed that there exists a target financial structure, which is optimal absent tax considerations, and that tax-motivated deviations from the target financial structure are associated with real costs. The most important implication of this specification is that the different sources of financing are imperfect substitutes. The optimal financial structure is thus shaped by tax incentives but is not tax-minimizing as would be the case if the different sources of financing were perfect substitutes. These properties are consistent with the empirical facts about the financial structure of multinational firms reviewed above. They are also consistent with the literature on the internal capital markets stressing the role of external capital markets, agency costs, rent sharing, and uncertainty about future earnings in shaping the financial structure of multinational firms.

4.1. Capital and Labor Market Equilibrium

We restate the profit function of the multinational firm in the following way:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0107
The first line reiterates the profit function of the basic model, whereas the second line captures the costs associated with deviations from the target financial structure. We make the following assumptions about the cost functions: (i)urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0108 where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0109 is the target level; (ii) urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0110; and (iii) urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0111. The same properties are assumed for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0112, and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0113. The assumptions about the cost functions imply that the marginal cost of moving a financial structure variable away from its target level is strictly increasing in the initial distance to the target level. We do not attach any particular interpretation to the cost functions but consider them a convenient modeling device that allows us to analyze the empirically relevant case of imperfectly substitutable sources of financing in a simple and flexible way. It should also be noted that the cost functions do not capture deep policy-invariant trade-offs within the firm. While they may be taken to be exogenous to the tax policies analyzed in the paper, they are likely to be endogenous to many other policies such as regulation of bankruptcies, creditor rights, and so on.
Analogously to the simple model, we rewrite the profit function in the following way:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0114
Multinational firms thus maximize π over urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0115. Using the identity urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0116, the first-order conditions for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0117, and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0118 can be stated as
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0119(13)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0120(14)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0121(15)
These equations uniquely determine the optimal financial structure of the multinational firm urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0122 for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0123. It is easy to see that in the absence of capital taxes, only the target financial structure satisfies the first-order conditions. It can be shown that a small increase in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0124 causes the following changes to the optimal financial structure of the subsidiary in country i: (i) an increase in external loans urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0125; (ii) an increase in internal loans from other countries urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0126, (iii) a decrease in internal loans from the same country urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0127; and (iv) a decrease in equity urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0128 (see Appendix). Intuitively, the firm responds to increased taxation in country i by adjusting the financial structure so as to reduce the share of the capital stock that is taxed in the country itself (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0129) and raise the shares of the capital stock that is taxed in other countries and untaxed (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0130). By the same logic, a small increase in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0131 causes a decrease in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0132 offset by increases in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0133 , urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0134 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0135.
The first-order conditions for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0136 can be stated as
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0137(16)
This equation uniquely determines urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0138 conditional on the capital structure.
The first-order conditions for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0139 can be stated as
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0140(17)
This equation determines the equilibrium wage rate:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0141
Given the equilibrium wage rate, the labor supply function (6) determines the equilibrium labor supply urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0142. The equilibrium capital stock urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0143 follows directly from urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0144 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0145.

4.2. Tax Policy

Private consumption and government expenditure are given by 5 and 7 with the single qualification that the parameters of the financial structure are endogenous in the present setting. We derive the following first-order conditions for utility maximization with respect to urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0146 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0147, respectively (see Appendix):
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0148(18)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0149(19)
where
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0150
Whereas 18 is identical to the equivalent in the simple model, 19 has an additional term urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0151, which represents the revenue effect of the adjustments to the optimal financial structure induced by a marginal increase in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0152. We note that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0153 is unambiguously negative, which derives from the fact that multinational firms respond to tax increases in country i by adjusting all dimensions of their financial structure in order to reduce the tax base in country i.
It follows from 18 and 19 that the following expression needs to be satisfied by an optimal tax mix urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0154:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0155
This is the equivalent of 12 and a similar argument applies: All terms except urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0156 are proportional to and have the opposite sign as urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0157, which implies that only a tax vector urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0158 with urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0159 can satisfy Equations 18 and 19. We summarize this analysis in the following proposition:

PROPOSITION 3.When operating subsidiaries have an optimally chosen financial structure and the different sources of financing are imperfect substitutes, the optimal capital tax rate is strictly positive.

Intuitively, capital taxes in country i trigger adjustments of the financial structure that erode the capital tax base in country i; however, evaluated at urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0160, the marginal deadweight loss is of second order. The revenue gain associated with exporting of capital taxes is of first order; hence, the optimal capital tax rate is strictly positive.

5. Two-Sector Economy

The baseline model assumes that all firms are financially integrated multinationals, whereas in the real world many firms are only present in a single country and have no financial links to foreign entities. To investigate whether our results are robust to the presence of domestic firms, this section extends the analysis to a setting where two sectors coexist in the economy: multinational firms producing with labor and mobile capital and domestic firms producing with labor and immobile capital (for instance, land or entrepreneurial human capital embedded in the immobile workers). In addition to their endowments of labor (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0161) and mobile capital (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0162), workers are endowed with urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0163 units of immobile capital that they supply inelastically to firms in the domestic sector. Workers can move costlessly between sectors, which implies that a single wage applies to the entire economy.

5.1. Capital and Labor Market Equilibrium

As in the baseline model, the optimal capital intensity of multinational firms urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0164 is determined uniquely by 2. Moreover, due to free entry in the multinational sector, the equilibrium wage rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0165 equals the wage rate that yields zero profits in multinational firms and is given by 4.

The profit function of domestic firms is given by
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0166
where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0167 is a standard production function with constant returns to scale and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0168 is the return to immobile capital. Domestic firms hire labor and immobile capital until
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0169(20)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0170(21)

Clearing of the market for immobile capital requires that demand equals the fixed supply urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0171. Hence, the equation urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0172 implicitly determines the equilibrium amount of labor employed in the domestic sector urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0173, whereas the equation urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0174 determines the equilibrium return to immobile capital urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0175. Profits in domestic firms are zero by Euler's theorem. The total amount of labor employed in the economy urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0176 is determined by (4), whereas the equilibrium amount of labor employed in the multinational sector urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0177 is given by urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0178 urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0179.

5.2. Tax Policy

Private consumption and government expenditure are given by
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0180(22)
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0181(23)
Compared to the analogous expressions in the baseline model, individuals now have income urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0182 from their endowments of immobile capital and the government raises revenue urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0183 from taxing immobile capital. Inserting 22 and (23) into the utility function, we can derive the first-order condition for utility maximization with respect to the labor tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0184 (see Appendix):
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0185(24)
where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0186 is the share of total employment in the multinational sector. Equation 24 differs from the analogous equation in the baseline model (10) only by the factor urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0187 in the last term inside the curly brackets, which implies that the labor tax ceteris paribus is associated with a smaller deadweight loss than in the one-sector model. Intuitively, the labor tax generates revenue in both sectors at the expense of a lower labor supply, but it is only in the multinational sector that a lower labor supply leads to a lower level of taxable capital.
Similarly, we derive the first-order conditions for utility maximization with respect to the capital tax rate urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0188 (see Appendix):
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0189(25)
where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0190 urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0191 is the intensity of domestically taxable capital in the multinational sector relative to the economy as a whole and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0192 is the share of the total capital tax base in the multinational sector. Equation 25 differs from the analogous equation in the baseline model 11 in two respects. First, all the terms related to changes in the capital tax base (collected in square brackets) are multiplied by the factor urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0193, which implies that the capital tax ceteris paribus is associated with a smaller deadweight loss than in the baseline model. While a small increase in the capital tax mechanically raises the revenue collected in both sectors, it is only in the multinational sector that it distorts the capital intensity; hence, the deadweight loss is decreasing in the employment share of the multinational sector. Second, the labor supply elasticity is multiplied by the factor θ. Intuitively, the cost of raising the capital tax rate in terms of a lower wage rate (leading to reduced labor supply and loss of labor tax revenue) is proportional to the intensity of (domestically taxable) capital in the multinational sector, whereas the benefit in terms of increased revenue is proportional to the intensity of (domestically taxable) capital in the economy as a whole. In the one-sector model, these two factors are the same and cancel out, but this is not necessarily the case in the present two-sector model.
Combining 24 and 25, it can easily be shown that an optimal tax mix must satisfy the following condition:
urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0194(26)

To proceed with the analysis, we distinguish between three cases. First, when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0195, the optimality condition simply requires that the expression inside the square brackets equals zero, which is identical to the optimality condition in the one-sector model 12. In this case, the labor tax and the capital tax distort the labor supply to precisely the same extent, so the optimal size of the capital tax again depends on the trade-off between the positive tax-exporting effect through intrafirm loans and the negative effect through distortion of the capital intensity in the multinational sector. While both of these effects are smaller in magnitude than in the one-sector model because they now only occur in one of the economy's two sectors, they are scaled down by the same factor urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0196, which means that the trade-off between them is unchanged. Hence, the optimal policy vector remains the same as in the one-sector model. This result, which mirrors Propositions 1 and 2, is summarized in Proposition 4.

PROPOSITION 4.When the two sectors are equally intensive in domestically taxable capital (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0197):

  • (A) The optimal capital tax rate is zero (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0198) when multinational firms are fully equity-financed (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0199).
  • (B) The optimal capital tax rate is positive (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0200) when multinational firms are partly financed with intrafirm loans (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0201).

Second, when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0202, all terms in 26 are proportional to and have the opposite sign as urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0203 except urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0204, which is positive, and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0205, which is negative. In the absence of intrafirm loans (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0206), the latter term dominates the former, in which case no positive value of urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0207 can satisfy the optimality condition. In the presence of intrafirm loans (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0208), the former term dominates the latter whenever θ is not too large, and in this case, only a positive value of urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0209 can satisfy the optimality condition. Intuitively, when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0210, the capital tax distorts the labor supply more than the labor tax relative to the revenue it raises, which implies that it can only be optimal to use it at a positive rate if the tax exporting effect through intrafirm loans is sufficiently large. These findings are summarized in Proposition 5.

PROPOSITION 5.When the multinational sector is more intensive in domestically taxable capital than the domestic sector (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0211):

  • (A) the optimal capital tax rate is nonpositive (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0212) when multinational firms are fully equity-financed (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0213);
  • (B) the optimal capital tax rate is positive (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0214) when multinational firms are partly financed with intrafirm loans (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0215) provided that θ is not too large.

Third, when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0216, all terms in 26 are proportional to and have the opposite sign as urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0217 except urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0218 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0219, the sum of which is strictly positive. It follows that only a positive value of urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0220 can satisfy the optimality condition. Intuitively, when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0221, the capital tax distorts the labor supply less than the labor tax relative to the revenue it raises, which implies that it is optimal to use it at a positive rate even without tax exporting through intrafirm loans. This result is summarized in Proposition 6.

PROPOSITION 6.When the multinational sector is less intensive in domestically taxable capital than the domestic sector (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0222), the optimal capital tax rate is positive (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0223) regardless of the financial structure of multinational firms.

In summary, this section has shown that, although differences in capital intensity across sectors affect the relative attractiveness of labor and capital taxes when the economy comprises both multinational and domestic firms, the basic tax-exporting mechanism identified in the main analysis still exists. In particular, there is a range of values of the key parameter θ where the optimal capital tax is zero when multinational firms are fully equity-financed and positive when they are partly financed with intrafirm debt.

6. Concluding Remarks

This paper has developed a model of corporate taxation in the presence of financially integrated multinational firms. The two key assumptions of the model—and the main departure from standard models of international taxation—relate to the internal capital markets of multinational firms. Specifically, it was assumed that multinational firms partly finance foreign investment with internal loans and that internal loans are not entirely driven by a profit-shifting motive. The main finding is that the presence of internal loans introduces a tax-exporting motive for corporate taxes. Intuitively, to the extent that multinational firms finance investment in one country with loans from affiliates in another country, the burden of corporate taxes in the latter country partly falls on investment and thus workers in the former country. Our model thus helps resolve the tension between the standard result that the optimal-source-based capital tax is zero and the casual observation that most countries employ corporate taxes at nonnegligible rates.

  • 1 These patterns are consistent with the findings of other papers. Also, based on the MiDi data set, Ramb and Weichenrieder (2005) report that German affiliates of non-German firms have an average total debt-asset ratio of 0.53, which breaks down into an external debt-asset ratio of 0.23 and an internal debt-asset ratio of 0.29. Based on data from the U.S. Internal Revenue Service, Altshuler and Grubert (2002) report an average total debt-asset ratio of 0.54 for foreign affiliates of U.S. firms with an average parent debt-asset ratio of 0.11. Desai, Foley, and Hines (2004) report similar figures based on data from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. The U.S. data sources do not distinguish between loans from other affiliates than the parent and loans from third parties and therefore do not contain sufficient information to compute internal debt-asset ratios.
  • 2 To see the difference, note that the theory developed by Fuest and Huber (2002) predicts a zero tax rate under the exemption principle, whereas our model implies a positive tax rate.
  • 3 While it is not straightforward to assess the separability assumption empirically, it is often used in the literature including Gordon (1986) and the survey chapter by Keen and Konrad (2013).
  • 4 The results extend to a corporate tax on profits with deductions for interest payments and taxation of interest income. A proof is available on request.
  • 5 The technical role of this assumption is to ensure that all operating entities in a given country have the same after-tax cost of capital.
  • 6 When a parent company transfers funds to a subsidiary in the form of equity, a number of formal requirements must be observed. The legal details vary across countries, but typically a decision to issue new shares must be adopted by the board of directors of the subsidiary, the decision needs the attestation of a notary public, the statutes of the subsidiary must be amended to reflect the higher share capital of the firm, and the amended statutes must be published in the official gazette. Moreover, repatriation of funds in the form of dividends is subject to a number of legal requirements and restrictions. For instance, interim accounts need to be drawn up and approved by an external auditor unless the distribution coincides with the closing of the annual accounts and dividends cannot be paid out of capital, reserves, or unrealized profits. Arguably, these legal requirements imply that nonnegligible administrative costs are associated with intrafirm transfers in the form of equity investments and dividend payments. By comparison, intrafirm transfers in the form of loans merely require that the managers of the lending and borrowing entities conclude a loan agreement.
  • 7 The survey chapter by Keen and Konrad (2013), for instance, also adopts the assumption that capital can only be taxed at the source and provides an insightful discussion of this assumption.
  • 8 See Johannesen (2014) and Johannesen and Zucman (2014) for recent analyses of offshore tax evasion.
  • 9 It may appear inconsistent that we allow taxation of firm interest income when we disallow taxation of household interest income. It should be noted, however, that firms differ fundamentally from households in the sense that all financial transactions are reflected in accounts that need the approval of an external auditor. While there are examples of firms rigging the books with or without the cooperation of auditors, these are arguably exceptions to the general rule that corporate accounts convey a truthful picture of the transactions in which the firm has engaged. Corporate accounts thus constitute by and large reliable financial information, on the basis of which capital taxation of firms' financial income may be enforced.
  • 10 Proposition 1 may easily be generalized to any set of parameters where operating subsidiaries are partly financed with a nonnegative fraction of external debt (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0325), a nonnegative fraction of internal debt from domestic lenders (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0326), and zero internal debt from foreign lenders (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0327).
  • 11 We assume away the possibility that one of the sectors crowd out the other sector altogether. Technically, this means that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0328 is sufficiently large such that the domestic sector always hires some labor and that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0329 is sufficiently small such that the domestic sector never hires all the labor in the economy.
  • 12 To see this, note that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0330 when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0331.
  • Appendix A

    1 Section 3.2.: Derivation of 811

    Country i maximizes individual utility with respect to its two tax policy instruments urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0224. The tax policies shape the economic equilibrium in the country itself urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0225 and in the countries to which it is connected by multinational firms urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0226 through equations 2, 4, and (6), whereas the return to capital r is given exogenously from the world capital market. This economic equilibrium, in turn, determines the outcomes of interest to the individual: private consumption urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0227 and government expenditure urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0228 given by 5 and 7, respectively.

    The first-order condition for utility maximization with respect to urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0229 reads
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0230(27)
    where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0231. Using expressions 5 and 7 and the definition of urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0232, we derive the following expressions:
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0233(28)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0234(29)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0235(30)
    Insert these expressions into 27 and use the first-order condition for optimal labor supply 6 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0236(31)
    It follows from 4 that
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0237(32)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0238(33)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0239(34)
    First, evaluate 31 for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0240 using 32:
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0241(35)
    Note that
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0242
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0243
    where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0244 follows from 6 and the assumption of separable utility. Insert these expressions into (A9) to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0245
    Divide by urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0246 and rewrite in terms of elasticities to obtain 10. Evaluate at urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0247 where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0248 to obtain 8.
    Second, evaluate 31 for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0249 using 33:
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0250(36)
    Note that
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0251
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0252
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0253
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0254
    where we have used that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0255 that follows from 6 under the assumption of separable utility. Insert these expressions into 36 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0256
    Divide by urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0257 and rewrite in terms of elasticities to obtain 11. Evaluate at urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0258 where urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0259 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0260 to obtain 9.

    2 Section 3.2.: Proof of Proposition 2

    We restate the equation that must be satisfied by an optimal tax mix:
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0261
    We write out the first, third, and fourth (set of) terms:
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0262
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0263
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0264

    Since urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0265 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0266 by 2 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0267 by assumption, it follows that all three (set of) terms are negative when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0268, zero when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0269 and positive when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0270. When the financial structure involves some cross-border internal lending (urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0271), the second set of terms urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0272 is strictly positive; hence, only when urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0273 can 12 hold.

    3 Section 4.1: Derivation of Responses of Financial Structure to Tax Change

    For expositional simplicity, we derive the optimal responses of the financial structure to tax policy changes for the case where internal loans into producing entities come from a single country j. In this case, the first-order conditions for the optimal financial structure of producing entities in country i 1315 simplify to
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0274(37)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0275(38)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0276(39)
    Now differentiate these three equations with respect to tax rates and the parameters of the optimal capital structure to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0277(40)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0278(41)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0279(42)
    Use 40 and 41 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0280(43)
    Use 42 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0281(44)
    We first derive the effect of a change in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0282. Insert 44 into 40 and then 43 into the resulting expression. Set urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0283 and rearrange to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0284(45)
    where
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0285
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0286
    Combine 45 with 43 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0287(46)
    Combine 45, 46, and 44 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0288(47)
    It follows from 4547 and the identity urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0289 that
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0290(48)
    Next, we derive the effect of a change in urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0291. Set urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0292, insert 43 into 40 and rearrange to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0293
    Rewrite as
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0294
    Use 43 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0295
    Insert into 44 and rearrange to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0296

    4 Section 4.2.: Derivation of 18 and 19

    The derivation of the first-order conditions for optimal tax policy follows Section 3.2. with the exception that the parameters of the financial structure are now endogenous. This has no implications for 28 and 30, whereas 29 becomes
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0297
    which is identical to 29 except for the last two terms that reflect the tax sensitivity of the financial structure. Note that tax-induced changes in the financial structure have no first-order impact on wages since the financial structure is initially optimized to maximize profits and thus wages. This is an application of the envelope theorem.
    Since the optimal financial structure is not affected by labor taxes, the first-order condition for the optimal labor tax is unchanged. The first-order condition for the optimal capital tax becomes
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0298
    Divide by urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0299 and rewrite in terms of elasticities to obtain 19.

    5 Section 5.: Derivation of 24 and 25

    The derivation of the first-order conditions for optimal tax policy follows Section 3.2. closely. To save space, we only restate equations that differ from their counterparts in that section.

    The first-order condition for utility maximization with respect to urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0300 remains 27, whereas the effect of tax rates on private consumption and public expenditure become
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0301(49)
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0302(50)
    where we have used 22 and 23. Together with 30, these two expressions can be inserted into (A1) to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0303(51)
    Evaluating this expression for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0304 using 32 yields
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0305(52)
    It follows from the first-order conditions for profit-maximizing in domestic firms that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0306: the endogenous domestic-sector variables urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0307 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0308 are uniquely determined by urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0309 and urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0310 that are both unaffected by the labor tax rate. Moreover, we derive the following relations between the labor tax rate and the mobile capital stock:
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0311
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0312
    Insert these expressions into 52 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0313
    Divide by urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0314 and rewrite in terms of elasticities to obtain 24.
    Evaluating 51 for urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0315 while using 33 yields
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0316(53)
    Note that
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0317
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0318
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0319
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0320
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0321
    where we have used that urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0322 which follows from 6 under the assumption of separable utility. Insert these expressions into 36 to obtain
    urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0323
    Divide by urn:x-wiley:10973923:media:jpet12192:jpet12192-math-0324 and rewrite in terms of elasticities to obtain 25.

    Biography

    • Niels Johannesen, Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Denmark ([email protected]).

      The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.