Volume 81, Issue 4 pp. 757-780
Feature Article
Full Access

Asymmetric Information, Self-selection, and Pricing of Insurance Contracts: The Simple No-Claims Case

Catherine Donnelly

Catherine Donnelly

Catherine Donnelly is at the Department of Actuarial Mathematics and Statistics, and the Maxwell Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh EH14 4AS, United Kingdom. Donnelly can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Martin Englund is at the Department of Economics and Business, Aarhus University, Denmark, and Codan Insurance, part of the RSA Group, Denmark. Englund can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Jens Perch Nielsen is at Cass Business School, City University, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, United Kingdom. Nielsen can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Carsten Tanggaard is at CREATES, Aarhus University, Denmark. Tanggaard can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. The authors wish to express their gratitude to an anonymous referee whose comments greatly improved the article. Carsten Tanggaard acknowledges support from CREATES, funded by the Danish National Research Foundation.Search for more papers by this author
Martin Englund

Martin Englund

Catherine Donnelly is at the Department of Actuarial Mathematics and Statistics, and the Maxwell Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh EH14 4AS, United Kingdom. Donnelly can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Martin Englund is at the Department of Economics and Business, Aarhus University, Denmark, and Codan Insurance, part of the RSA Group, Denmark. Englund can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Jens Perch Nielsen is at Cass Business School, City University, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, United Kingdom. Nielsen can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Carsten Tanggaard is at CREATES, Aarhus University, Denmark. Tanggaard can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. The authors wish to express their gratitude to an anonymous referee whose comments greatly improved the article. Carsten Tanggaard acknowledges support from CREATES, funded by the Danish National Research Foundation.Search for more papers by this author
Jens Perch Nielsen

Jens Perch Nielsen

Catherine Donnelly is at the Department of Actuarial Mathematics and Statistics, and the Maxwell Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh EH14 4AS, United Kingdom. Donnelly can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Martin Englund is at the Department of Economics and Business, Aarhus University, Denmark, and Codan Insurance, part of the RSA Group, Denmark. Englund can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Jens Perch Nielsen is at Cass Business School, City University, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, United Kingdom. Nielsen can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Carsten Tanggaard is at CREATES, Aarhus University, Denmark. Tanggaard can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. The authors wish to express their gratitude to an anonymous referee whose comments greatly improved the article. Carsten Tanggaard acknowledges support from CREATES, funded by the Danish National Research Foundation.Search for more papers by this author
Carsten Tanggaard

Carsten Tanggaard

Catherine Donnelly is at the Department of Actuarial Mathematics and Statistics, and the Maxwell Institute for Mathematical Sciences, Heriot-Watt University, Edinburgh EH14 4AS, United Kingdom. Donnelly can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Martin Englund is at the Department of Economics and Business, Aarhus University, Denmark, and Codan Insurance, part of the RSA Group, Denmark. Englund can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Jens Perch Nielsen is at Cass Business School, City University, 106 Bunhill Row, London EC1Y 8TZ, United Kingdom. Nielsen can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. Carsten Tanggaard is at CREATES, Aarhus University, Denmark. Tanggaard can be contacted via e-mail: [email protected]. The authors wish to express their gratitude to an anonymous referee whose comments greatly improved the article. Carsten Tanggaard acknowledges support from CREATES, funded by the Danish National Research Foundation.Search for more papers by this author
First published: 20 June 2013
Citations: 5

Abstract

This article presents an optional bonus-malus contract based on a priori risk classification of the underlying insurance contract. By inducing self-selection, the purchase of the bonus-malus contract can be used as a screening device. This gives an even better pricing performance than both an experience rating scheme and a classical no-claims bonus system. An application to the Danish automobile insurance market is considered.

Introduction

If one tells the truth, one is sure, sooner or later, to be found out.

Oscar Wilde

In a world with two levels of risk and asymmetric information, where the insurance company cannot distinguish between customers from the two risk groups, there is no pooling equilibrium and there may not be an equilibrium at all (Rothschild and Stiglitz, 1976). In a pooling equilibrium, the lower risk policyholders subsidize the higher risk policyholders. If the policyholders are aware of their risks and the difference is too large between risk and price, the lower risk individuals will not buy insurance. Thus, either the market for insurance breaks down or each type of policyholder buys an insurance contract with a payoff that caters to the specific riskiness of the policyholder. This idea of sufficiently tailor-made (i.e., differentiated) contracts may not fit exactly with what we see in current insurance markets. Insurance contracts offered by insurance companies are only to some extent differentiated, depending on the sophistication of the models, the available data, and regulations. However, Allard, Cresta, and Rochet (1997) show that pooling equilibria may exist if even the slightest distributional cost exists. Differences in risk aversion can also make policyholders with different risks accept pooling (at least to some extent), according to Rothschild and Stiglitz (1976).

Covariate-based regression is generally used to differentiate pricing and the most widely used models for this are generalized linear models (GLMs); see Pinquet (2001) for applications in actuarial science and McCullagh and Nelder (1989) for a general discussion of the statistical theory of GLMs. One way to improve the a priori pricing is to make use of a posteriori corrections based on experience rating, such as credibility theory and bonus-malus systems (BMS). Simple time-independent credibility models with extensions to both time-dependence and multivariate experience rating are found in Pinquet, Guillén, and Bolancé (2001) and Englund et al. (2009). Brouhns et al. (2003) provide a quick survey of different types of BMS. Unfortunately, these experience-based methods have a limited impact when individual claim information is rare, as for new policyholders, and it may take several years of observation before the precision is reasonable. However, Donnelly, Englund, and Nielsen (2013) find evidence of adverse selection within the Danish automobile insurance market, meaning that the degree of coverage chosen by the policyholder is based on the ex ante assessment that a policyholder makes of his riskiness and wealth. Therefore, we seek new ways to differentiate the policyholders by risk at the very outset, that is, at the time of purchase of the insurance product.

This article gives examples of an insurance contract that may induce self-selection within the existing risk classes of the rating scheme. The new type of insurance contract has some features that are not found in contracts of standard BMS. Similar to BMS, the payoff that is offered to policyholders depends on the actual number of experienced claims during each insurance period, but the contract has a more general form of payoff than a standard contract with bonus. The payoff can be tailor-made to individual policyholders’ needs or preferences. Implicit in this is the idea that insurance companies should offer a menu of contracts in such a way that self-selection is induced among the policyholders. Hence, we allow for an extended individual choice compared to standard BMS.

With such a contract the insurer will be able to differentiate the insurance premium for each period of time to an even greater extent, which makes it more competitive due to the separating effect. This is desirable since adverse selection can cause inefficiency in insurance contracts, reducing the benefit of taking an insurance for the lower classes of risk since the price will be too high in relation to the risk (Akerlof, 1970; Rothschild and Stiglitz, 1976; Stiglitz, 1977). For recent contributions on the subjects of asymmetric information, adverse selection, deductibles, and bonus systems, see Snow (2009), Spreeuw and Karlsson (2009), and Kim et al. (2009).

We use policyholder and claims data from a Danish insurance company to investigate the hypothesis that such a contract will in fact induce self-selecting behavior, in addition to the decision of buying the insurance, at the differentiated prices of the rating scheme. Other recent approaches to assessing individual customer risk and relating it to pricing are Guillén et al. (2012) and Thuring et al. (2012).

The article is arranged as follows. In the section titled “The New Insurance Contract,” a heterogeneity model for the data and the new insurance contract are defined. “Comparison of the Add-On to Other Pricing Methods” gives the first numerical study, as well as describing the data set and the pricing methods used to measure the pricing precision of the new insurance contract. In the section titled “Individual Choice and Self-Selection,” we investigate the effects of individual choice on the pricing precision, based on an expected utility representation and private information. We finish with “Conclusion.”

The New Insurance Contract

First, a model for insurance claims when policyholders are heterogeneous is presented. Second, the insurance contract is introduced to exhibit features useful for inducing self-selection among insurance customers. Finally, we illustrate the efficiency of the proposed insurance contact using Danish automobile insurance data.

The usual assumptions used in models on adverse selection are maintained in this article: individual information is costly to observe by the insurer, neither the frequency nor the claim size are functions of the actions of the policyholders, the provision of the insurance is costless, and the insurer is risk neutral while the policyholders are risk averse, having the same twice-differentiable, increasing, and strictly concave utility function urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0001.

A Model for Heterogeneous Policyholders

Let us consider the number of claims, urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0002, for individual urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0003 in insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0004 on one particular coverage (i.e., a product). We consider one coverage at a time and assume that the events in different coverages are independent. We assume that every policyholder has a latent individual risk profile urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0005, which summarizes the informational asymmetry and is a realization of a positive random variable urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0006. The latent variable urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0007 is considered to be a random effect for the insurer but known by the policyholder.

Conditional on urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0008, the number of claims urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0009 is assumed to be Poisson distributed with expectation urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0010, in which urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0011 allows for the insurer's prior knowledge about the individual urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0012 in time period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0013. Specifically, denoting by urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0014 a column vector of covariates, such as age, sex, geographical area, or other relevant variables, and by urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0015 the duration of period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0016 covered for policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0017, then
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0001
in which the constant urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0018 is a column vector of parameters and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0019 denotes the transpose of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0020. When covariates are used to price insurance, it is assumed that individuals with the same characteristics have the same risk. However, the introduction of an individual risk profile into the model means that policyholders with the exact same set of covariates may differ in risk due to unobservable characteristics. Examples of these unobservable characteristics for automobile insurance may be aggressiveness while driving and the temperament of the driver.

The pairs urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0021 are independent random vectors, where urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0022 are independent and identically distributed (iid) random variables with urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0023 and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0024.

Since we will only consider full coverage insurances in what comes next, the cost of claims will not affect the individual decision rules or choices. Hence, we consider only the number of claims urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0025 rather than the aggregate cost of the claims made by individual urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0026 in insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0027.

Suppose that the insurer wishes to price the contract at the actuarially fair value. If the latent individual risk profile urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0028 is observable by each policyholder and insurer, then we have symmetric information. In that case, the insurance contract is simple: in each period the insurer offers to cover all losses for each individual against an insurance premium
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0002
However, when the insurer cannot observe the latent individual risk profile urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0029, the actuarially fair value of the insurance premium is
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0003
In the latter case of asymmetric information, there is no adjustment to the insurance premium for the individual's risk profile. In the following section, we propose a way to enable the insurer to gain information about the individual's risk profile urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0030.

The Add-On to the Standard Insurance Contract

Now we consider an add-on to the standard insurance contract, which allows for the policyholder's individual risk profile urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0031. To keep the discussion simple, we assume that the discount rate is zero.

In addition to the premium urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0032, policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0033 who accepts the add-on will pay an entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0034. If the policyholder makes no claims during the insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0035, the insurer will pay an amount urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0036 to the policyholder, in which the constant urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0037 is called the dividend. In other words, a policyholder who makes no claims during the insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0038 gets back his entrance fee plus a dividend at the end of the insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0039. If the policyholder makes one claim or more, then the insurer pays nothing to the policyholder in respect of the add-on (although the cost of the claims made under the standard insurance contract are covered as usual). The add-on to the standard insurance contract has a binary nature: either policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0040 gets the payment urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0041 at the end of insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0042, or he does not.

We focus our analysis on the simplest (one-period) setting in which the add-on is a one-period contract. Policyholders decide at the start of the insurance period whether or not to accept the add-on, and the contingent payment made at the end of the insurance period is distinct from the premium that would be paid in the next insurance period. Extensions of this simple setting are discussed in the following section, “Discussion of the Add-On.”

We assume that the contingent payment urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0043 is made directly to policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0044 at the end of the insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0045. In a more realistic setting, it may be tax efficient to reduce instead the insurance premium in the subsequent insurance period by the amount of the contingent payment.

The payments in the add-on could be restructured so that the policyholder pays nothing at the start of the insurance period. Then if policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0046 makes no claims, he would receive a payment of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0047 from the insurer at the end of the insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0048. Otherwise, policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0049 pays urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0050 to the insurer at the end of the insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0051. All of the results in our simple setting are identical with this alternative payment structure. It also allows the identification of the payment urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0052 as a bonus and the payment urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0053 as a malus.

However, paying the entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0054 up front has the advantage of allowing us to bypass punishment rules in environments where they are forbidden, such as in some health insurance systems (e.g., see Riedel, 2006). The absence of a reward at the end of the insurance period in the case where no claims occur (i.e., receiving nothing) replaces the punishment decision of the alternative payment structure (i.e., having to pay a malus urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0055 to the insurer). It may also be more attractive way of framing the add-on to the policyholder (see Johnson et al., 1993). Note that BMSs come in many variants in real life, as well as in the literature; for the latter, examples are Baione, Levantesi, and Menzietti (2002), Denuit et al. (2007), Lemaire and Zi (1994), Lemaire (2004), Moreno, Vázquez, and Watt (2006), and Pinquet (1997).

Mathematically, the payment from the add-on to policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0056 at the end of insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0057 is represented by the random variable
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0004
When making decisions regarding the add-on, the policyholder will take into account his conditional probability of claims
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0005
Thus, the conditional distribution of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0058 is
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0006
Having described the structure of the add-on, it remains to fix the values of the entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0059 and the dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0060. The entrance fee, urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0061, can be set either individually or collectively. This will be a strategic decision of the insurer and something we discuss in the sequel.

The dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0062 is calculated in this article via the actuarial net premium principle (see Young, 2006). The net premium principle is justifiable if we can assume that volatility is essentially nonexistent, that is, if the insurer sells enough iid policies so that the Law of Large Numbers applies. However, the dividend can be calculated via any other suitable principle, for example, the expected value premium principle: urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0063, for some urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0064.

Under the actuarial net premium principle, we set the entrance fee equal to the expected payment from the add-on, that is,
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0007(1)
We assume that the insurer must offer the add-on contract ex ante to the policyholder, with the amounts urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0065 and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0066 fixed at the start of insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0067. The insurer cannot change urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0068 during insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0069 in light of the decision of policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0070 to accept the add-on or not. This does not preclude the insurer from changing the risk classification of policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0071 in subsequent insurance periods, based on his decision to accept the add-on in the current insurance period. We do not explore this interesting avenue of research in this article. Instead, our focus is on the pricing precision of the add-on within the current insurance period. This is important to know, to see if there is a cost to the insurer in offering the add-on. In fact, our results show that the insurer's pricing precision may be increased significantly by offering the add-on.
Defining the unconditional probability of claims of policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0072 in insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0073
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0008
the (unconditional) distribution of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0074 is
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0009
Substituting urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0075 into Equation (1), we get
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0010(2)
Once the insurer has chosen urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0076, the value of the dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0077 is fixed by the above equation. Note that the insurer sets the dividend based on urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0078, the average probability of making a claim. In comparison, the policyholder evaluates the offered contract based on their individual probability of making a claim, urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0079.

Discussion of the Add-On

The add-on is a voluntary investment in addition to the original insurance contract. The add-on should be appealing to the customer who is a better-than-expected risk. Assuming this attractiveness is communicated to the customer, it is then for the customer to judge if he is a better-than-expected type. In this sense, there is a clear incentive from the customer's perspective to reveal his private knowledge. Consequently, the add-on is linked more directly to the economic discussion of asymmetric information than are classical BMSs.

Superficially, it seems that our simple no-claims example is similar to a “money-back” structure because money is paid out at the end of a claim-free year. Indeed, in the one-period case, the add-on clause has many similarities to a BMS. This can be seen by assuming a multiperiod setting in which the payments from the one-period add-on are paid only upon renewal of the insurance contract in the subsequent insurance period. In that case, the add-on is not very different from a BMS in the long run.

However, when generalizing the basic idea of paying money up front, that is, the entrance fee, to more complex pricing structures, such generalizations would differ fundamentally from other natural developments of a BMS. We could construct an add-on that is a 5-year or 10-year contract rather than a 1-year contract. A long-term contract gives the customer the full advantage of being a better-than-expected risk at the same time as providing a clear customer loyalty situation for the company. Furthermore, the add-on does not have to be restricted to the simple no-claims case. For example, one could introduce a threshold such the customers can have claims paid out up to some amount while still being in the class of customers getting a payout. Or one could simply say that the customer pays his own claims with the revenue from the add-on contract, as long as the revenue is large enough to pay the claims.

For example, suppose that the add-on is a 5-year contract. At the start of the 5-year period, the customer pays the standard insurance premium and the entrance fee. The entrance fee is calculated using the customer's expected experience over the 5-year period, rather than on observed experience data. During the 5 years, the standard insurance premium is adjusted using the emerging experience. The new idea is that we adjust also a historically already-paid premium. Aside from the initial entrance fee, the contract is structured so that the customer does not pay any more in premiums than if he had not bought the add-on. In other words, the buyer of the add-on cannot lose more than the entrance fee. That leaves the insurance company with a risk for which it charges an insurance premium in a similar way to the one-period case considered in this article. The distinction of moral hazard and dynamic selection on unobservables as analyzed in Abbring et al. (2003) and Abbring, Chiappori, and Pinquet (2003) based on observed data might be further developed and improved while incorporating future data in the consideration.

Comparison of the Add-On to Other Pricing Methods

We want to compare the insurance contract with a 1-year add-on against different pricing methods, using Danish automobile insurance data from 2001 to 2004. The accuracy of each pricing method is assessed by estimating the sum of squared errors (SSE) across all individual policyholders. Here, the error is defined as the net payment made by the insurer to the policyholder during an insurance period. The most efficient pricing method is the one that has the lowest SSE.

The idea behind using the SSE is that the insurer wants to break even on each contract. A premium that is too low will result in an economic loss. A premium that is too high will result in a loss of policyholders to another insurer that is offering a lower premium. More precisely, and since we only will investigate the product portfolio of one insurer, we assume that the insurer is a risk-neutral competitive specialist, whose expected profit for each policy is zero, as in Glosten and Milgrom (1985). The minimum SSE is expected in the theoretical situation where each customer pays exactly his own claim costs to the insurance company. Although the results below should clearly be interpreted in light of this, a low SSE seems to be a reasonable description of the insurance company's optimization problem (Bühlmann and Gisler, 2005).

Data Preparation and Model Validity

The data set that we analyze consists of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0080 policyholders in the personal lines portfolio of a Danish insurance company. The data set contains the variables used by the pricing department at the insurance company for each of the years during the period. For example, the covariates are: policyholder's demographic characteristics such as age, gender, geography; policyholder's car characteristics: brand, size of engine, model year, initial value of the car, commercial vehicle or not, main vehicle or not.

The data set was selected from more than urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0081 policyholders in the same portfolio. Policyholders with missing values and obvious outliers were removed. We chose the policyholders with exactly one automobile insurance policy, which has full coverage, full duration for each year of the period 2001–2004 and with no experience rating. In order to compare the classical no-claims bonus with the add-on as far as possible, each policyholder has to fulfill the criteria of the classical bonus, to the extent that the bonus is only dependent on the claim experience. Therefore, we further restricted our selection to policyholders who, in addition to the automobile insurance, have purchased a building and personal property insurance policy with full duration in the period 2001–2004.

The actual number of claims experienced for policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0082 in year urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0083 is denoted urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0084 and, as all policies have full annual duration, urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0085. By a covariate-based regression method (using GLM and maximum likelihood), we obtained the estimated expected number of claims urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0086. However, in our data set there is a difference between the total expected and total experienced number of claims due to the pricing procedure, namely, the rating scheme is estimated on all policyholders of the automobile portfolio, while we use only a subset of these. One might suspect that policyholders with full duration in 4 consecutive years, and who have purchased at least three insurance products, have a better claim history than we expected, even though total duration (seniority) is not a significant variable in the rating scheme. Due to this difference and our interest to investigate the performance of various pricing methods, we scaled the original claim frequency estimates urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0087 of the regression by multiplying each of them by a factor urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0088. These new claim frequency estimates urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0089 were then used to perform the analyses of this article.

Table 1 summarizes the claim information for each year in the period 2001–2004 for the data set of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0090 policyholders.

Table 1. Claims Summary of the Data Set
Year urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0204
2001 2002 2003 2004
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0205 1,604 3,381 5,264 7,007
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0206 1,644 3,441 5,264 6,969
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0207 7,128 6,058 5,165 4,531
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0208 7,128 6,068 5,365 5,153
  • Notes: Cumulative number of experienced claims, cumulative number of expected claims, the number of policyholders with no claims, and the number of policyholders with fewer claims than expected, for each year of the period 2001–2004 for the data set of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0209 policyholders. The actual and expected number of claims by policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0210 in year urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0211 is denoted urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0212 and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0213, respectively, and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0214 denotes the zero–one indicator function.

Empirically, we get a dispersion index of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0091 for the data set, which supports the correctness in assuming a conditional Poisson distribution, that is, assuming the existence of an individual latent risk profile.

Pricing Methods

We investigated five pricing methods for the insurance contract. The premiums for the year 2004 were calculated based on the data in years 2001–2003. The premiums and the actual claims experience in 2004 were then used to calculate the SSE for each method.

The five pricing methods, with their numerical index, are the following:
  • 1. Flat rate. The mean value estimator, or the flat rate, method with insurance premium urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0092. For this pricing method, the premium charged is identical for all policyholders:

    urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0011
    The flat rate method is the simplest possible estimator with an expected nonnegative profit. Based on the data in years 2001–2003, we find urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0093, meaning that, on average, there is approximately one claim every fifth year.

  • 2. Regression. The covariate-based regression method with insurance premium urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0094. It is the pricing method used by the Danish insurance company from whom we obtained the data and we use it as the baseline pricing method.

  • 3. Credibility. The experience rating method based on the one-dimensional homogeneous credibility estimator, with insurance premium urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0095. Bühlmann and Gisler (2005) provide an excellent survey on credibility theory.

  • 4. No-claims BMS. The classical, market-based, no-claims BMS with premium urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0096. In this case, if certain criteria are satisfied, the policyholder is granted a bonus expressed as a percentage of the premium. The bonus is given if the following criteria are fulfilled: the policy has a duration of at least 3 years, and no claims are reported during both the last 3 years and the current insurance period. For the given data set, the bonus is 10 percent. Normally, this requires that all policyholders pay 3–4 percent more of the original actuarial premium up front, in order that the portfolio is financially balanced. However, for the data subset of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0097 policyholders, the additional payment is 9.533 percent. The reason is due to the data selection: every policyholder in the data subset is in the bonus system and has the opportunity of getting a bonus. We lack the policyholders who subsidize the bonus system by not having the opportunity of getting one. Consequently, the additional payment is higher.

  • 5. Add-on. The standard insurance contract with an add-on. The premium charged for the standard insurance contract is urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0098 and the entrance fee for the add-on is urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0099. In this section of the article, we assume that all policyholders buy the add-on, so that the total amount charged to policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0100 is urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0101. This assumption will be removed in the section “Individual Choice and Self-Selection.”

    The dividend of the add-on is calculated for each policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0102 through Equation 10. This requires an estimator of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0103. First, we expanded urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0104 as a second-order Taylor series around urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0105, with a remainder term. Based on the data set, the empirical mean value of the remainder term is negligible (it is less than urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0106). Hence, taking the expectation of the Taylor expansion, we assumed the expected value of the remainder term was zero. The resulting estimator is urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0107, in which urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0108.

    Figure 1 shows the distribution of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0109 in the data set. The dividend is calculated as urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0110 for each policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0111. Thus, each policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0112 is offered an individually determined add-on, with entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0113 and dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0114. We discuss below the choice of the entrance fee.

Details are in the caption following the image
Distribution of the Estimated Values of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0192

Notes: As we use Equation (2) to calculate the dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0189 then, by Equation (4), urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0190 for policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0191.

A First Numerical Study

As we assume that the cost of claims urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0115, the SSE for pricing methods urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0116 is defined as
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0012
Due to the structure of the add-on, we calculate the SSE for urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0117 as
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0013
in which urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0118 equals one if urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0119, and zero otherwise.

Instead of reporting the absolute values of the SSE, we use the scaled SSE for each pricing method. It is calculated by dividing urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0120 by urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0121, that is, the SSE of the regression method, for each urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0122.

To fix the entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0123 for the add-on, in this section we assume it is a constant multiple of the premium urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0124 charged for the standard insurance contract to policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0125. Investigating the scaled SSE for the interval urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0126, we obtained Figure 2.

Details are in the caption following the image
Pricing Precision of the Add-On

Notes: Here the entrance fee of policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0193 is calculated as urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0194, for urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0195 and all policyholders are assumed to accept the add-on. The circles in the figure show the scaled SSE of the add-on contract in the year 2004 for different values of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0196. The minimum scaled SSE occurs at urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0197. The horizontal line is the scaled SSE of the no-claims BMS method. For an entrance fee of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0198 or more, the SSE is lower for the add-on than for the no-claims BMS method, in the investigated range.

The minimum SSE for the add-on contract occurs at urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0127 across the data set. We used this choice of the entrance fee to compare the pricing precision of the add-on contract with the other pricing methods. The results are shown in Table 2.

Table 2. Pricing Precision of Various Pricing Methods
Scaled SSE Relative Improvement
Pricing Method urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0215 Description urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0216 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0217
1 Flat rate urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0218 N/A
2 Regression urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0219 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0220
3 Credibility urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0221 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0222
4 No-claims BMS urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0223 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0224
5 Add-on urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0225 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0226
  • Notes: Scaled SSE for each pricing method and the increase in the SSE over the regression method, relative to the improvement in the SSE by moving from the flat rate method to the regression method, for the year 2004. The actual urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0227.

The difference in performance of the flat rate and the regression estimator is quite important since it illustrates why insurance companies have pricing departments. The credibility method, no-claims BMS method, and add-on method all use individual claim information. Therefore, they are expected to perform better than the other two ones, as is borne out by the numerical results.

Table 2 shows that the credibility method gives an additional improvement of 25 percent over the regression method relative to the improvement due to moving from the flat rate method to the regression method. Even so, it is not as good as we anticipated based on earlier studies, such as Englund et al. (2008) and Englund et al. (2009). However, the performance of a pricing method also depends on the type of coverage and data set. It may be that our data set is too limited; 4 years may be too few to fully benefit from the credibility approach.

In comparison, the performance of the no-claims BMS method is surprisingly good. It gives an additional improvement of 54 percent over the regression method compared to moving from the flat rate method to the regression method. It is also a rather simple method. These type of classical bonus systems are however afflicted with some drawbacks regarding fairness and stability aspects. Fairness: giving a fixed percentage in bonus is advantageous for the expected low-risk policyholders and disadvantageous for the expected high-risks compared to their probability of reporting claims. However, if the insurer has a strategy toward expected low risks, then it can be justified, or at least explained by, the insurer. Stability: if all customers qualify for the bonus system (e.g., they purchase the required number of products), then the system would not be stable, in the sense that the insurer will lose money if the initial extra payment is not re-estimated. Remember that one of the fundamental principles of insurance is that the policyholder should pay for the expected transferred risk, not the outcome.

The add-on deals with these fairness and stability aspects while retaining the advantages of simplicity and low requirements on information. It can perform even better than both the credibility method and the 10 percent no-claims BMS, depending on the choice of the entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0128. The scaled SSE of the add-on with the optimal entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0129 is exceptionally low, and it is almost 20 times the improvement of implementing the regression method over the flat rate method.

The drawback is that the optimal entrance fee is over three times the premium. It is doubtful that an average policyholder would pay the optimal entrance fee of more than three times his annual insurance premium up front and risk losing it all. For these reasons, and encouraged by the promising results in Table 2, we extend our study to allow for the policyholders to choose whether or not to buy the add-on.

Individual Choice and Self-Selection

In the previous section we saw that the pricing precision could be increased by setting individual risk-based bonuses. However, the analysis was under the assumption that all the policyholders bought the add-on, no matter how high the entrance fee. Here we relax the assumption.

Each policyholder buys the standard insurance contract, and then decides whether or not to buy the add-on. We expect that this will induce self-selection among policyholders within the same risk class of the rating scheme. The policyholders make their choice based on an expected utility decision rule; namely, they buy the add-on if it gives them a higher expected utility of wealth compared to not buying the add-on. Thus, we are introducing the individual risk preferences of the policyholders.

As we are interested in the performance of the add-on both as a pricing method and as a separating (self-selection) mechanism, we focus only on the decision to buy the add-on or not, and ignore the decision on whether to buy insurance or not. Moreover, for the numerical study below, the individuals in the data set have already decided to buy insurance. As before, we assume a null discount rate.

The Individual Decision Rule

Denote by urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0130 the wealth of individual urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0131 at the start of insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0132, that is, the initial wealth prior to the decision about insurance coverage. The initial wealth consists of all the policyholder's possessions including cash, financial assets, and the object that is insured. The policyholder is assumed to have more wealth than the insured object and enough cash to pay the premium urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0133 of the standard insurance contract and the entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0134, that is, urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0135. Although there is no need to have the urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0136 subscript in this section, we maintain it here for consistency with the notation in the rest of the article.

There are only two different outcomes for the terminal wealth depending on the binary decision on whether to buy insurance with or without an add-on. The outcomes are summarized in Table 3.

Table 3. Wealth at the End of Insurance Period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0228
Event Conditional Probability Decision
Buy Insurance Without Add-On Buy Insurance With Add-On
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0229 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0230 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0231 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0232
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0233 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0234 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0235 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0236
  • Notes: The wealth at the end of insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0237 depends on the decision to buy the add-on or not, and whether the policyholder has no claims or not, assuming a null discount rate.
It follows that the policyholder will decide to buy the add-on if
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0014
that is,
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0015(3)
We assume the policyholder to have a constant relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility function. For urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0137, the CRRA utility function is defined as
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0016
The choice of CRRA finds support in Friend and Blume (1975), Pindyck (1988), and Szpiro (1986). Friend and Blume conclude that an individual's coefficient of relative risk aversion is “on average well in excess of one and probably in excess of two,” based on data on household asset holdings. Pindyck finds support for a relative risk aversion coefficient between 3 and 4 whereas Szpiro finds support for a relative risk aversion coefficient between 1.2 and 1.8, based on data on property–liability insurance. In our simple scenario, we assume a relative risk aversion coefficient urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0138, and investigate a number of alternative scenarios in which we alter the initial wealth and other parameters.
Define
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0017(4)
We call urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0139 the investment ratio for policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0140 in insurance period urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0141. Under the CRRA assumption, we can rewrite the decision rule (3) as
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0018
In other words, for an arbitrary policyholder with a fixed risk aversion coefficient urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0142, his decision to buy the add-on depends on three things: his individual conditional probability of claim urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0143, the ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0144, and the investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0145.
If we further specialize to the case where the ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0146 is determined by the insurer through Equation 10 and the relative risk aversion coefficient urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0147, the decision rule reduces to
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-math-0019(5)
Thus, in this simple scenario, as the entrance fee decreases and hence urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0148 decreases, more policyholders will accept the add-on. Additionally, we see that as long as a policyholder's conditional probability of claim urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0149 is less than the average probability of claim urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0150, it is possible to find an investment ratio at which the policyholder will buy the add-on. However, we do not explore further in this article precisely how the add-on can act as a screening device. Instead, we analyze the impact on the SSE of allowing the policyholders the choice to buy the add-on, and how the SSE varies with different investment ratios offered to the policyholders.

A Second Numerical Study

On the Danish data set of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0151 policyholders, we investigate three scenarios for the selection of the investment ratio using the decision rule (5). First, all policyholders are offered the same investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0152. Next, each policyholder is offered the investment ratio that maximizes his individual expected utility from the purchase of the add-on. Finally, the policyholders are offered an entrance fee that is the same constant multiple of their standard insurance premium across all policyholders.

We use the regression method to calculate the premium for the standard insurance contract. As before, the parameters are estimated from the data in years 2001–2003. In particular, the (private) risk profile urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0153 of each policyholder is taken to be his second-last credibility estimate, based on the information in years 2001–2003.

In the first scenario, all policyholders are offered the same investment ratio, that is, urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0154 for all urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0155. Thus, policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0156 is offered an add-on with entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0157 and dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0158. Note that under the decision rule (5), each policyholder evaluates the add-on based on urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0159, and not directly on the entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0160 or his initial wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0161. Figure 3 shows how many policyholders would choose to buy the add-on at different levels of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0162.

Details are in the caption following the image
Demand Curve of the Add-On

Notes: The number of policyholders who would buy the add-on, based on the decision rule (5), as the constant investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0199 offered to all policyholders increases.

Under the first scenario, we find which investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0163, offered to all the policyholders at the start of 2004, would have minimized the SSE at the end of 2004. Of course, this is not a method that an insurer could use a priori to select the investment ratio. However, it does give us some insight into the potential offered by add-on. Since we do not know the wealth of each policyholder, the analysis is done assuming that all policyholders start the year 2004 with the same amount of wealth. The results are summarized in Table 4.

Table 4. Pricing Precision With Optimal Constant Investment Ratio
Initial Wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0238 in DKK
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0239 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0240 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0241 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0242 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0243
Optimal constant urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0244  0.06203  0.06226  0.06188  0.05431  0.01395
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0245 0.9735 0.9483 0.8804 0.7866 0.5534
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0246 0.8179 1.5957 3.6914 6.5864 13.7840 
Number of buyers of add-on 3,679 3,670 3,687 4,078 5,147
  • Notes: Optimal investment ratio if all policyholders are proposed with the same investment ratio and are assumed to have the same risk aversion coefficient urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0247 and the same initial wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0248. The optimal investment ratio is the one that minimizes the SSE. The values of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0249 and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0250 are derived from Table 2.

In Table 4, we see that the optimal constant investment ratio offered to the entire portfolio is decreasing as the initial wealth increases. The consequence is that the SSE decreases as wealth increases, since each policyholder is bearing more of his own risk. The increasing number of policyholders buying the add-on is due to the decreasing urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0164, under the assumption that the risk aversion coefficient remains constant. Notable is that for urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0165, the entrance fee is around DKK 620 (ignoring the premium for the standard insurance contract, as it varies between policyholders) and already we get an additional improvement in the SSE of 81.79 percent compared to going from the flat rate to the regression estimator. Just by adding individual choice!

The average experienced claim frequency in year 2004 for the policyholders who buy an add-on at these portfolio optimal investment ratios is 18.84 percent, while it is 22.65 percent for those who do not buy the add-on. As urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0166 and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0167 are estimated from the data in years 2001–2003, this means that the policyholders who decide to buy the add-on continue to show lower risk in the year 2004.

In the next scenario, we suppose that the insurer offers to each policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0168 the investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0169 that maximizes his expected utility from the add-on (i.e., the urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0170 that maximizes the left-hand side of Equation 15). This means that policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0171 is offered an add-on with entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0172 and dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0173. If the decision rule (5) is satisfied for this choice of the investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0174, then policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0175 will buy the add-on. Figure 4 shows the distribution of the estimated values of the optimal individual investment ratios urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0176 across the data set.

Details are in the caption following the image
Distribution of the Estimated Values of the Individually Optimal Investment Ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0203

Notes: There are urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0200 policyholders who will decide to not accept the add-on, regardless of the offered investment ratio, as the estimated value of their conditional probability of claims urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0201 is greater than the estimated value of their unconditional probability urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0202 (recall decision rule (5)). The optimal investment ratio for these policyholders is set to zero.

In total, urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0177 policyholders will choose to buy the add-on at their individually optimal urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0178. Table 5 shows the scaled SSE under different assumptions on initial wealth, under this scenario.

Table 5. Pricing Precision With Individually Optimal Investment Ratio
Initial Wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0251 in DKK
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0252 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0253 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0254 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0255 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0256
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0257 0.9707 0.9427 0.8659 0.7623  0.4125
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0258 0.9043 1.7685 4.1389 7.3364 18.1327
Number of buyers of add-on 5,246 5,246 5,246 5,246 5,246
  • Notes: Scaled SSE when the estimated value of the optimal investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0259 of each individual is used as entrance fee, and each policyholder is assumed to have the same initial wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0260 and risk aversion coefficient urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0261. The number of buyers of the add-on is constant, as their optimal investment ratio is independent of wealth. The values of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0262 and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0263 are derived from Table 2.

We get an even better pricing method than in the first scenario for all assumptions on initial wealth. However, in practice, for policyholders with large initial wealth, such as DKK urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0179, there should be some restrictions for the entrance fee to be a good pricing method. For instance, a restriction could be that the net dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0180 may not exceed the actuarial premium, or else the SSE will increase as the dividend increases. For implementational reasons, the insurer might offer the policyholder a stepwise function, instead of a continuum of eligible entrance fees. The precision of the function may depend on the precision of risk perception of the policyholders and the costs of implementation, systems maintenance, and so on.

We find that the average experienced claim frequency in year 2004 for those policyholders who buy an add-on at their individually optimal investment ratio urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0181 is 20.85 percent, while it is 21.00 percent for those who do not buy the add-on. Thus, while policyholders who decide to buy the add-on continue to show lower risk in the year 2004, the difference in risk is not as large as in the first scenario, in which all policyholders were offered the same constant investment ratio.

In the last scenario, each policyholder is offered an entrance fee that is a proportion of his individual standard insurance premium. It is the same scenario as in the subsection “A First Numerical Study,” except that now the policyholders make a decision to accept the add-on or not. For some constant urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0182, policyholder urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0183 is offered an add-on with entrance fee urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0184 and dividend urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0185. The motivation is that it might be easier to relate to the insurance premium than the initial wealth, for both the policyholder and the insurer. The proportion urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0186 is chosen as the one that would have minimized the SSE at the end of year 2004. Table 6 shows the results, assuming all policyholders have the same initial wealth.

Table 6. Pricing Precision With Entrance Fee a Multiple of the Individual Annual Insurance Premium
Initial Wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0264 in DKK
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0265 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0266 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0267 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0268 urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0269
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0270 0.06366 0.2851 0.8576 1.605 3.566
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0271 0.9837 0.9560 0.8948 0.8147 0.6046
urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0272 0.5031 1.3580 3.2469 5.7191 12.2037
Number of buyers of add-on 4,781 4,147 4,010 4,178 5,148
  • Notes: Scaled SSE for different initial wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0273, when the entrance fee is a multiple of the individual annual insurance premium. The multiple is the same for each policyholder across the data set, while the annual insurance premium is individual. Here, the policyholders choose individually whether to accept the add-on or not. The values of urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0274 and urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0275 are derived from Table 2.

The scaled SSEs in Table 6 are less than under the no-claims BMS method (whose scaled SSE is 0.9828; see Table 2), except at an initial wealth urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0187. The performance is improving as the initial wealth increases, but so is the entrance fee.

Generally, the SSE is somewhat higher than in the other two scenarios, for the same initial wealth (compare Table 6 with Table 4 and Table 5). In spite of this, the number of policyholders buying the add-on is larger than in the scenario in which all policyholders were offered the same investment ratio (compare Table 6 with Table 4).

The average experienced claim frequency in year 2004 for those policyholders who buy an add-on when the proportion urn:x-wiley:00224367:media:jori1520:jori1520-umath-0188 is chosen as the one that gives the lowest SSE is 18.79 percent, while it is 23.16 percent for those who do not buy the add-on. That is, the policyholders who decide to buy the add-on continue to show lower risk in the year 2004.

Conclusion

We have proposed an alternative way to turn a problem of asymmetric information into a solution of how to price insurance in groups with heterogeneous risk. The design of the proposed add-on can vary in many ways. Both the criterion of getting a dividend and the size of the dividend can easily be modified to suit a specific business line or area. For instance, no-claims are neither common nor relevant as a criterion for policyholders in areas with a high claim frequency, such as glass insurance within commercial transport. There, a criterion based on a bound on the number or cost of claims, either fixed or in relation to the expectation, might be more appropriate. However, as our intention has been to keep the model as simple and as descriptive as possible in this article, we kept the criterion of no-claims.

The size of the entrance fee will be a strategic decision based on either policyholder insight or the business strategy of the insurer, or by the policyholders themselves. We have showed that there might be both entrance fees and dividends that exist at realistic levels.

Under the assumptions made, we have found that each policyholder has an optimal entrance fee, depending on his initial wealth, individual risk profile, and risk aversion. Since the insurer usually does not know the initial wealth or risk aversion of each individual, the insurer may let the policyholder choose the size of the entrance fee in order to get the optimal effect of the self-selection mechanism when pricing insurance. The higher the number of choices offered to the individual, the larger becomes the price–coverage differentiation, thereby increasing the competitiveness of the insurance product, due to fair pricing. However, the add-on will become less effective as a screening device. The more the price is differentiated, the less the add-on separates the policyholders into groups of buyers or not, and vice versa.

Although the one-period add-on analyzed in this article is close to a classical BMS, its generalization to a multiperiod add-on opens up avenues for further developments. Our approach is an alternative to a BMS, rather than a reformulation of it, with a direct link to revealing a customer's asymmetric information. Exploring the pricing and efficiency of a multiperiod add-on contract is a topic for future research.

The main conclusion of this article is that the potential of the add-on increases with freedom of individual choice, while the efficiency is limited to the self-awareness of the individuals. But the most applicable conclusion is that by giving the policyholder an individually set contingent payment based on his expected risk, instead of a collective fixed bonus rate, we get a fairer and more competitive pricing system.

Notes

  • 1 Lazar and Denuit (2012) provide an analysis of the relationship of premiums with interest rates, among other variables.
  • 2 Ulm (2012) considers the pricing of insurance contracts in a broader framework involving tax.
  • 3 We thank the referee for pointing out this approach.
    • The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.