Evolutionary Alternatives to Equilibrium Economics
Some Suggested Applications
Joseph E. Pluta
St. Edward's University
The author is Professor of Economics at St. Edward's University. Direct correspondence to: Joseph E. Pluta, Department of Economics, 3001 S. Congress Ave., Austin, TX 78704; email: [email protected]. He would like to thank two anonymous referees for helpful comments made on an earlier draft.
Search for more papers by this authorJoseph E. Pluta
St. Edward's University
The author is Professor of Economics at St. Edward's University. Direct correspondence to: Joseph E. Pluta, Department of Economics, 3001 S. Congress Ave., Austin, TX 78704; email: [email protected]. He would like to thank two anonymous referees for helpful comments made on an earlier draft.
Search for more papers by this authorAbstract
Built on the fictional concept of equilibrium, mainstream economics provides a method of analysis that, when paired with the calculus, enables relatively easy identification of maximum and minimum values. Lacking empirical evidence of its behavioral assumptions, the profession accepts such familiar claims as consumer maximization of utility and business firm maximization of profit or revenue. In place of the relatively static concept of equilibrium, the Veblen-Myrdal notion of circular and cumulative causation (CCC) arguably has greater descriptive capability and more penetrating insight for policy recommendations. This article traces the historical origins of both concepts and argues that CCC offers considerable potential for a broad, dynamic, interdisciplinary, more thorough, and more accurate analytical framework. Specific examples of work that has been done along with suggestions for future applications of this concept are given.
References
- Armstrong, H., and J. Taylor. (2000). Regional Economics and Policy, 3rd ed. London: Blackwell Publishing.
- Berger, S. (2008). “Circular Cumulative Causation (CCC) a la Myrdal and Kapp—Political Institutionalism for Minimizing Social Costs. Journal of Economic Issues 42(2): 357–365.
- Berger, S. (2009a). “Myrdal's Institutional Theory of the State: From Welfare to Predation—and Back? Journal of Economic Issues 43(2): 353–360.
-
Berger, S. (Ed.). (2009b). The Foundations of Non-Equilibrium Economics: The Principle of Circular and Cumulative Causation. London: Routledge.
10.4324/9780203873731 Google Scholar
- Canterbery, E. R. (1987). The Making of Economics, 3rd ed. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth Publishing Company.
- Cherrier, B. (2009). “Gunnar Myrdal and the Scientific Way to Social Democracy, 1914–1968. Journal of the History of Economic Thought 31(1): 33–55.
- Darwin, C. (1859/1956). The Origin of Species. New York: Frederick Ungar Publishing.
-
Dunn, S. P., and S. Pressman. (2005). “The Economic Contributions of John Kenneth Galbraith.
Review of Political Economy
17(2): 161–209.
10.1080/09538250500067254 Google Scholar
- Fukuyama, F. (1992). The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Avon Books.
- Fusfeld, D. R. (2000). “A Manifesto for Institutional Economics. Journal of Economic Issues 34(2): 257–265.
- Galbraith, J. K. (2001). The Essential Galbraith. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
- Gordon, W. (1980). Institutional Economics: The Changing System. Austin: University of Texas Press.
- Hall, J., and U. Ludwig. (2009). “Gunnar Myrdal and the Persistence of Germany's Regional Inequality. Journal of Economic Issues 43(2): 345–352.
- Hall, J., and O. Whybrow. (2008). “Continuity and Continuousness: The Chain of Ideas Linking Pierce's Synechism to Veblen's Cumulative Causation. Journal of Economic Issues 42(2): 349–355.
- Hamilton, D. B. (1953). Evolutionary Economics: A Study of Change in Economic Thought. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.
- Hayden, F. G. (2006a). Policymaking for a Good Society: The Social Fabric Matrix Approach to Policy Analysis and Program Evaluation. New York: Springer.
- Hayden, F. G. (2006b). “The Inadequacy of Forrester System Dynamics Computer Programs for Institutional Principles of Hierarchy, Feedback, and Openness. Journal of Economic Issues 40(2): 527–535.
- Hayden, F. G. (2008). “Circular and Cumulative Causation and the Social Fabric Matrix. Journal of Economic Issues 42(2): 389–397.
- Ho, P. S. (2009). “An Institutionalist's Policy Advice to Address International Inequalities: The Contributions of Gunnar Myrdal. Journal of Economic Issues 43(2): 337–344.
- Krugman, P. (1996). “ What Economists Can Learn from Evolutionary Theorists.” Paper presented to the European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy.
- Lane, D. C. (2008). “The Emergence and Use of Diagramming in Systems Analysis: A Critical Account. Systems Research and Behavioral Science 25(1): 3–23.
- Lee, F. S. (2006). Post Keynesian Price Theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
- Leijonhufvud, A. (1968). On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory. New York: Oxford University Press.
- Leijonhufvud, A. (1970). “Notes on the Theory of Markets. Intermountain Economic Review 1(1): 1–13.
- McChesney, F. S., W. F. Shughart II, and D. D. Haddock. (2004). “On the Internal Contradictions of the Law of One Price. Economic Inquiry 42(4): 706–716.
- Means, G. C. (1972). “The Administered Price Theory Reconfirmed. American Economic Review 62(3): 292–306.
- Minsky, H. P. (1986). Stabilizing an Unstable Economy. New Haven: Yale University Press.
-
Mirowski, P. (1989). More Heat Than Light: Economics as Social Physics, Physics as Nature's Economics. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
10.1017/CBO9780511559990 Google Scholar
- Myrdal, G. (1944). An American Dilemma. New York: Harper and Brothers.
- Myrdal, G. (1978). “Institutional Economics. Journal of Economic Issues 12(4): 771–785.
- Newton, I. (1687). Principia Mathematica. London: S. Pepsys.
- Nichols, M., O. Pavlov, and M. J. Radzicki. (2006). “The Circular and Cumulative Structure of Administered Pricing. Journal of Economic Issues 40(2): 517–526.
- O'Hara, P. A. (2002). “The Contemporary Relevance of Thorstein Veblen's Institutional-Evolutionary Political Economy. History of Economics Review 35(1): 78–103.
- O'Hara, P. A. (2008). “Principle of Circular and Cumulative Causation: Fusing Myrdalian and Kaldorian Growth and Development Dynamics. Journal of Economic Issues 42(2): 375–387.
- Phillips, A. W. (1954). “Stabilization Policy in a Closed Economy. Economic Journal 64(2): 290–305.
- Phillips, A. W. (1957). “Stabilization Policy and the Time-Forms of Lagged Responses. Economic Journal 67(2): 265–277.
- Pluta, J. E. (2008). The Market: Mainstream and Evolutionary Views. Dubuque, IA: Kendall Hunt.
- Pressman, S. (2006). Fifty Major Economists, 2nd ed. London: Routledge.
- Pressman, S., and R. Holt. (2008). “Nicholas Kaldor and Cumulative Causation: Public Policy Implications. Journal of Economic Issues 42(2): 367–373.
- Radzicki, M. J. (2003). “Mr. Hamilton, Mr. Forrester, and a Foundation for Evolutionary Economics. Journal of Economic Issues 37(1): 133–173.
- Radzicki, M. J., and L. Tauheed. (2007). “ In Defense of System Dynamics: A Response to Professor Hayden.” Paper presented at the International Conference of the System Dynamics Society in Boston, MA.
- Richardson, G. P. (1986). “Problems with Causal Loop Diagrams. System Dynamics Review 2(3): 158–170.
- Richardson, G. P. (1991). Feedback Thought in Social Science and Systems Theory. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
- Richardson, G. P. (1997). “Problems in Causal Loop Diagrams Revisited. System Dynamics Review 13(4): 247–252.
-
Toner, P. (1999). Main Currents in Cumulative Causation: The Dynamics of Growth and Development. London: Macmillan.
10.1007/978-0-333-98289-1 Google Scholar
- Tustin, A. (1953). The Mechanism of Economic Systems. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
- Varian, H. R. (1992). Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd ed., New York: W. W. Norton.
- Veblen, T. B. (1898, 1993). “ The Instinct of Workmanship.” In A Veblen Treasury: From Leisure Class to War, Peace, and Capitalism. Ed. R. Tilman. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.