HISTORY-DEPENDENT PATHS AND TRADE GAINS IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY WITH A PUBLIC INTERMEDIATE GOOD*
Manuscript received December 2009; revised June 2010.
Abstract
This study reexamines McMillan's (International Economic Review 19 (1978), 665–78) analysis of a dynamic small open economy with a public intermediate good. Concerning the trade patterns of the open economy, we find results that were overlooked in McMillan's analysis. Among others, if labor endowment is of intermediate size, there are two saddle-point steady states, and the initial stock of the public good determines the long-run trade pattern. We also add a gains-from-trade analysis to McMillan's model and demonstrate that if the economy has a comparative advantage in a good with productivity less sensitive to the public intermediate good, the economy may lose from trade at the steady state.
1. introduction
The supply of public intermediate goods has a great impact on a nation's economic development, welfare, and other important matters. In particular, for a trading country, the supply of public intermediate goods plays an important role in determining trade patterns. For example, during recent decades, the government's role in supporting scientific research and the development of human resources has become important in the rapid economic movement toward globalization. Among trading and well-developed countries, how and on what scale governments should supply these public intermediate goods are recognized as important policies for gaining economic advantage. Therefore, it is imperative to study the role of public intermediate goods in relation to international trade.
The subject itself is not new. In fact, Manning and McMillan (1979) studied trade patterns in a small open Ricardian economy with a public intermediate good. Extending their analysis, Tawada and Abe (1984) and Tawada and Okamoto (1983) examined various traditional trade theorems, including the pattern of trade theorem in the Heckscher–Ohlin type of small open economy with a public intermediate good. Furthermore, Suga and Tawada (2007) recently treated the analysis in a Ricardian two-country model. All these studies are, however, static analyses.
When we consider public intermediate goods such as scientific research, transportation systems, and the development of human resources, they had better be treated as capital stocks. Thus, the analysis should be performed in a dynamic framework. Moreover, among theoretical studies of international trade, in general, the studies incorporating a dynamic aspect have become rigorous in recent years (see, for example, Mountford, 1999; Deardorff, 2001a, 2001b; Hu et al., 2005, 2006). Thus, it is worthwhile and interesting to examine trade theory with public intermediate goods in a dynamic framework.
Among international trade theories featuring a public intermediate good, only McMillan (1978) offers a dynamic analysis investigating trade patterns in a dynamic framework, where a public intermediate good can be accumulated over time as a capital stock. McMillan (1978) considered a small open economy with two private production sectors, one public intermediate good sector, and one primary factor of production. Moreover, two private goods are produced using the primary factor and the public intermediate good, which in turn is produced by the primary factor.2 In his model, McMillan showed that the stock of the public intermediate good determines the slope of the production possibility frontier (PPF) and thus determines the pattern of international trade.
However, McMillan's (1978) examination of the dynamic paths and the resulting steady-state solutions was hardly adequate. Thus, in this study, we reexamine his work and present a more precise analysis. In particular, he stated in his Proposition 3 that a unique steady state necessarily exists. We will, however, prove the possibility that two saddle-point stable steady states exist. Thus, our result concerning the patterns of trade along the time path is not necessarily similar to the result he obtained. In particular, we show that if the labor endowment is of moderate size, two saddle-point stable steady states appear, and the patterns of trade heavily depend on the initial stock of the public intermediate good.
In addition to trade patterns, whether trade is gainful is also an important concern. Therefore, we add this into our analysis, since McMillan (1978) did not address it. Concerning the gains from trade in a static economy with public intermediate goods, if a public intermediate good is supplied under the Lindahl rule and if the economy is stable, any small open country necessarily gains from trade. This is because the PPF is unaffected and equilibrium is efficient before and after trade. In a dynamic framework, however, the stock of a public intermediate good may be depreciated; thus, the PPF may shrink in the long run, creating a possibility of trade losses. In fact, we show the possibility of trade losses at a steady-state equilibrium.
This article is organized into the following sections. Section 2 presents the model, and Section 3 explains the dynamic system drawn from the model. Section 4 is devoted to the analysis of specialization patterns. Section 5 considers transition paths from autarky to free trade. Section 6 is allocated to an analysis of gains from trade, and the last section summarizes our results and provides remarks.
2. the model
Following McMillan (1978), we consider a small open economy containing two private sectors, one public production sector, and one primary factor of production, which is assumed to be labor. The two private sectors are assumed to be sectors 1 and 2, where goods 1 and 2 are produced, respectively, under constant returns to scale technology with respect to labor. The public sector produces a public intermediate good with decreasing returns to scale technology with respect to labor. The public intermediate good can be accumulated, and its accumulated stock serves in the production in private sectors as a positive external effect without congestion between sectors. Total labor endowment is assumed to be given and constant over time.















3. dynamic system
In this section, we inspect the properties of a dynamic system. Defining the production elasticity of the public intermediate good stock in sector i as , we make the following assumption regarding the impact of the public intermediate good on industries:
Assumption 1 η1(R) > η2(R).
The above assumption implies that the public intermediate good serves more significantly in the production in sector 1 than in that of sector 2.
Let be a function satisfying the relation of p=A2(R)/A1(R). Then,
is decreasing in p under Assumption 1.









In sum, we obtain a dynamic system of θ and R in the small open economy as described by (10) and (11).
4. pattern of specialization
We now investigate the steady state of the dynamic system constructed by (10) and (11). The steady state is a point (R*, θ*) satisfying . Let
be a solution of
, and consider the following three cases separately:
-
Case 1:
,
-
Case 2:
,
-
Case 3:
.
In Case 1, a unique steady state where the economy specializes in good 1 exists and is saddle-point stable. This case occurs when is sufficiently large and/or p is adequately high. If, in addition,
and
are sufficiently close to each other, the steady state is globally saddle-point stable. This particular case is displayed in Figure 1, where the gap between points A and B becomes sufficiently small and thus a global saddle path can exist.8

unique and globally saddle-point stable steady state in case 1: ()
In order to see the production pattern on the global saddle path, we suppose in Figure 1 that the initial point is C, where . Thus, starting at R0, R gradually approaches the steady state E along the saddle path. Then, only good 2 is produced until R reaches
. Once R reaches
, the economy diversifies in production, and after R exceeds
, only good 1 is produced.
In Case 2, where a unique steady state exists, the economy specializes in good 2 and the steady state is saddle-point stable. This case appears if L is sufficiently small and/or p is adequately low. Because this case becomes the reverse of Case 1, we omit the figure. Again, if and
are sufficiently close to each other, the steady state becomes globally saddle-point stable.
Concerning the production pattern on the global saddle path, we suppose that the initial stock is given by . Starting at R0, R gradually approaches the steady state along the saddle path. Then, the production pattern of this economy becomes the opposite of Case 1 with respect to time path, implying that production is first specialized in good 2, then diversified at
, and finally specialized again, but in good 1 after R exceeds
.
Finally, we consider Case 3. In this case, three steady states, E1, E2, and Ed, exist, as shown in Figure 2.9E1 and E2 are locally saddle-point stable, whereas Ed is unstable.10 At E1 and E2, the economy is specialized in goods 1 and 2, respectively. Both goods are produced at the unstable steady state Ed.

multiple steady states in case 3: ()
In this case, the initial level of R determines the steady-state specialization pattern: If , the steady state is E1 and production is specialized in good 1, whereas if
, the steady state is E2 and production is specialized in good 2.
Now we summarize the results obtained in this section as the following theorem:
Theorem 1 If
L
is sufficiently large and/or
p
is adequately high to satisfy the condition that
, there exists a unique saddle-point stable steady state where the economy is specialized in good 1. IfLis sufficiently small and/orpis adequately low to satisfy the condition that
, there exists a unique saddle-point stable steady state where the economy is specialized in good 2. Otherwise, three steady states appear, two of which are saddle-point stable and one of which, with diversified production, is unstable. In this case, if the initial stock of the public intermediate good is less [resp. greater] than
, specialization occurs in good 2 [resp. good 1] in the steady state.
McMillan (1978) asserted in his Proposition 3 that a unique steady state necessarily exists. Although our model is a special case of McMillan (1978), it shows the possibility of two saddle-point stable steady states. This particularly occurs in the case where the size of labor endowment and the level of the consumption-good price ratio are moderate. In this case, which steady state is finally realized relies on the initial level of the public intermediate good stock. If the initial stock level is sufficiently high [low], a country can have an advantage in the industry whose productivity is more [less] sensitive to the amount of public intermediate good stock. Thus, the country tends to specialize in the commodity of this industry.
The difference between our and McMillan's results is due to the fact that McMillan disregarded the nonsmoothness property of the curve at the incomplete specialization point.11 Moreover, McMillan considered the phase where the public intermediate good is not produced. However, in our analysis, such a phase never occurs, implying that the public intermediate good is produced at all points of time.
5. transition from autarky to free trade
We examined the pattern of production at a steady state in a small trading country. Advancing our analysis, we now investigate how the production pattern varies along the time path starting from the autarkic steady-state equilibrium as an initial position. For this purpose, let us derive the autarkic equilibrium of this economy.





Thus, the dynamic system of a closed economy is built by dynamic equations (11) and (13). Because the locus of is a convex combination of θ=η1(R)/[(ρ+β)R] and θ=η2(R)/[(ρ+β)R], the locus is monotonically downward sloping. As in the case of free trade, the locus of
is drawn as a monotonically upward-sloping curve. Therefore, there exists a unique autarkic steady state denoted by
.
We consider a transition from autarky to free trade and investigate how a country's welfare changes by this transition. We assume that the economy is initially in a steady state. Then, if (we refer to this case as Case I), the country has a comparative advantage in good 1. This is because the autarkic steady-state price pa satisfies the condition that
, and
is a decreasing function of p. Thus, the autarkic steady-state price pa is lower than the international price p.
Figure 3 illustrates the transition from autarky to free trade in Case I, where E and Ea in the figure are the steady states under free trade and autarky, respectively. As is clear from this figure, Case I occurs when the labor endowment is sufficiently large so that holds.12

transition from autarky to free trade: case I ()
Likewise, if (we refer to this as Case II), the country has a comparative advantage in good 2. This case occurs when labor endowment is sufficiently small so that
holds. The transition from autarky to free trade corresponding to this case can be shown diagrammatically in a fashion similar to Case I, and thus we omit the figure.13
In sum, we assert
Theorem 2 Suppose that the country is initially in an autarkic steady state. Then, after opening trade, if the country faces a higher [resp. lower] international relative price of good 1 than its autarkic steady-state relative price, the country specializes in good 1 [resp. good 2] at the steady state under free trade, as well as during the entire period of reaching the steady state.
McMillan (1978) did not investigate the transition path from the autarkic steady state to the free-trade steady state after the opening of trade. The above theorem shows that changes in the pattern of specialization never occur along any transition path from autarky to a free-trade steady state.
6. gains from trade
In the previous section, we inspected the autarkic steady-state equilibrium. Using this result, we investigate whether trade is gainful or harmful at the steady state. Let us first present the following lemma:
Lemma 1 Suppose that the economy specializes in good i under free trade ( i= 1, 2 ). Then, evaluated at the steady state, Ai(R)(L−LR) is increasing in R .


Now we investigate whether a small open economy gains or loses from trade at the steady state. We separately consider the two cases examined in the previous section.
Case I. .
In this case, it must hold that . Given this and Lemma 1, it holds that
, i= 1, 2. This implies that the long-run PPF expands after trade. Moreover, because p > A2(R*)/A1(R*), the trading line (with slopep) of the economy specializing in good 1 is drawn outside the long-run PPF under free trade. Comparing the steady-state consumption point under autarky, which is on the autarkic long-run PPF, and the steady-state consumption point under free trade, which is on the trading line, it follows that the steady-state welfare level is higher under free trade than under autarky. In other words, the economy unambiguously gains from trade at the steady state in this case.
Case II. .
In this case, we have . Given this and Lemma 1, it is observed that the long-run PPF contracts after trade. This case is illustrated in Figure 4, where the downward straight line closer to the origin exhibits the long-run PPF under free trade, whereas the other downward straight line is that of autarky.

the gains or losses from trade in case II
In contrast to Case I, the trading line and the long-run PPF intersect in this case. This means that, depending on preferences, the economy may gain or lose from trade at the steady state. For example, if the autarkic steady-state equilibrium pair of consumption is given by point A1 in Figure 4, trade enhances welfare at the steady state. On the other hand, if the autarkic steady state is on A2, trade reduces welfare at the steady state.
Now we establish the following theorem:
Theorem 3 If
, trade is unambiguously gainful at the steady state. However, if
, trade is possibly harmful at the steady state.
As seen in Figure 4, the possibility of trade losses is caused by a shrinkage of the long-run PPF. This is the result of a long-run decrease in the stock of a public intermediate good caused by the opening of trade. This case must appear in a country that has an advantage in the good with less sensitive productivity of the public intermediate good, and thus in a country with a small labor endowment.
Note that in the present analysis of gains from trade, we focus only on the steady state. Thus, we show the possibility of trade losses at the steady state. In the case of the entire period encompassing the transition to the steady state, this possibility of trade losses may not disappear. To make a complete analysis, we also need to compare the transition path of a closed economy with that of an open economy.14
7. summary and remarks
In this study, we reexamined McMillan's (1978) analysis of trade patterns and added the gains-from-trade analysis of a small Ricardian economy in a dynamic framework. Our investigation into the patterns of trade presented the following results. If the labor endowment is sufficiently large (small), a small open country specializes in a good whose productivity is more (less) sensitive to the public intermediate good in the long run. In the case where the sensitivity of the productivity to the public intermediate good stock is similar between private industries, a switch in trade patterns along the dynamic path can occur. This possibility of a switch is not properly presented in McMillan (1978), even though the model is essentially the same. Moreover, we demonstrated that, if the labor endowment is of intermediate size, there are two saddle-point stable long-run equilibria, and the initial stock of the public intermediate good determines the long-run trade patterns according to the history-dependent time paths. This aspect was also overlooked in McMillan's analysis.
Concerning trade gains, we obtained the following results. If a country enjoys a comparative advantage in producing a good whose output is more responsive to the stock of a public intermediate good, the economy unambiguously gains from trade at the steady state. In contrast, if a country enjoys a comparative advantage in producing a good whose output is less responsive to the public intermediate good stock, the economy may lose from trade.
We need to extend our present analysis of the Ricardian type to that of the non-Ricardian type. In a two-factor case like the Heckscher–Ohlin model, if we assume that public or private capital can be accumulated, the factor endowment ratio varies from time to time. Therefore, the theorems depending on the factor endowment ratio may be seriously affected in a dynamic trade model. Of another importance is to treat the present issue in a two-country dynamic framework. Thus, we need to handle the two state variables, each of which is a public intermediate good stock specific to the country. Then the model becomes that of a dynamic game. Finally, though we focused on public goods serving private production, it may be interesting to consider the role of public consumption goods in international trade. In fact, Connolly (1970) treated an international trade analysis in a static two-country framework with public consumption good long time ago. However, the dynamic analysis still remains in this case.
Footnotes









