Volume 53, Issue 1 pp. 303-314
Full Access

HISTORY-DEPENDENT PATHS AND TRADE GAINS IN A SMALL OPEN ECONOMY WITH A PUBLIC INTERMEDIATE GOOD*

Akihiko Yanase

Akihiko Yanase

Tohoku University, Japan; Nagoya University, Japan

Search for more papers by this author
Makoto Tawada

Makoto Tawada

Tohoku University, Japan; Nagoya University, Japan

We thank Professors Murray Kemp, Minoru Kunizaki, Yukio Karasawa, Yuichi Furukawa, and Ishidoro Mazza, participants of workshops at Chukyo University and the University of Catania, and three anonymous referees for their helpful comments on earlier manuscript drafts. Financial support from the Ministry of Education, Culture, Sports, Science and Technology is gratefully acknowledged. Please address correspondence to: Akihiko Yanase, Graduate School of International Cultural Studies, Tohoku University, 41 Kawauchi, Aoba-Ku, Sendai 980-8576, Japan. E-mail: [email protected].

Search for more papers by this author
First published: 22 February 2012
Citations: 11

Manuscript received December 2009; revised June 2010.

Abstract

This study reexamines McMillan's (International Economic Review 19 (1978), 665–78) analysis of a dynamic small open economy with a public intermediate good. Concerning the trade patterns of the open economy, we find results that were overlooked in McMillan's analysis. Among others, if labor endowment is of intermediate size, there are two saddle-point steady states, and the initial stock of the public good determines the long-run trade pattern. We also add a gains-from-trade analysis to McMillan's model and demonstrate that if the economy has a comparative advantage in a good with productivity less sensitive to the public intermediate good, the economy may lose from trade at the steady state.

1. introduction

The supply of public intermediate goods has a great impact on a nation's economic development, welfare, and other important matters. In particular, for a trading country, the supply of public intermediate goods plays an important role in determining trade patterns. For example, during recent decades, the government's role in supporting scientific research and the development of human resources has become important in the rapid economic movement toward globalization. Among trading and well-developed countries, how and on what scale governments should supply these public intermediate goods are recognized as important policies for gaining economic advantage. Therefore, it is imperative to study the role of public intermediate goods in relation to international trade.

The subject itself is not new. In fact, Manning and McMillan (1979) studied trade patterns in a small open Ricardian economy with a public intermediate good. Extending their analysis, Tawada and Abe (1984) and Tawada and Okamoto (1983) examined various traditional trade theorems, including the pattern of trade theorem in the Heckscher–Ohlin type of small open economy with a public intermediate good. Furthermore, Suga and Tawada (2007) recently treated the analysis in a Ricardian two-country model. All these studies are, however, static analyses.

When we consider public intermediate goods such as scientific research, transportation systems, and the development of human resources, they had better be treated as capital stocks. Thus, the analysis should be performed in a dynamic framework. Moreover, among theoretical studies of international trade, in general, the studies incorporating a dynamic aspect have become rigorous in recent years (see, for example, Mountford, 1999; Deardorff, 2001a, 2001b; Hu et al., 2005, 2006). Thus, it is worthwhile and interesting to examine trade theory with public intermediate goods in a dynamic framework.

Among international trade theories featuring a public intermediate good, only McMillan (1978) offers a dynamic analysis investigating trade patterns in a dynamic framework, where a public intermediate good can be accumulated over time as a capital stock. McMillan (1978) considered a small open economy with two private production sectors, one public intermediate good sector, and one primary factor of production. Moreover, two private goods are produced using the primary factor and the public intermediate good, which in turn is produced by the primary factor. In his model, McMillan showed that the stock of the public intermediate good determines the slope of the production possibility frontier (PPF) and thus determines the pattern of international trade.

However, McMillan's (1978) examination of the dynamic paths and the resulting steady-state solutions was hardly adequate. Thus, in this study, we reexamine his work and present a more precise analysis. In particular, he stated in his Proposition 3 that a unique steady state necessarily exists. We will, however, prove the possibility that two saddle-point stable steady states exist. Thus, our result concerning the patterns of trade along the time path is not necessarily similar to the result he obtained. In particular, we show that if the labor endowment is of moderate size, two saddle-point stable steady states appear, and the patterns of trade heavily depend on the initial stock of the public intermediate good.

In addition to trade patterns, whether trade is gainful is also an important concern. Therefore, we add this into our analysis, since McMillan (1978) did not address it. Concerning the gains from trade in a static economy with public intermediate goods, if a public intermediate good is supplied under the Lindahl rule and if the economy is stable, any small open country necessarily gains from trade. This is because the PPF is unaffected and equilibrium is efficient before and after trade. In a dynamic framework, however, the stock of a public intermediate good may be depreciated; thus, the PPF may shrink in the long run, creating a possibility of trade losses. In fact, we show the possibility of trade losses at a steady-state equilibrium.

This article is organized into the following sections. Section 2 presents the model, and Section 3 explains the dynamic system drawn from the model. Section 4 is devoted to the analysis of specialization patterns. Section 5 considers transition paths from autarky to free trade. Section 6 is allocated to an analysis of gains from trade, and the last section summarizes our results and provides remarks.

2. the model

Following McMillan (1978), we consider a small open economy containing two private sectors, one public production sector, and one primary factor of production, which is assumed to be labor. The two private sectors are assumed to be sectors 1 and 2, where goods 1 and 2 are produced, respectively, under constant returns to scale technology with respect to labor. The public sector produces a public intermediate good with decreasing returns to scale technology with respect to labor. The public intermediate good can be accumulated, and its accumulated stock serves in the production in private sectors as a positive external effect without congestion between sectors. Total labor endowment is assumed to be given and constant over time.

The production function of each private sector is assumed to take the following form: (i= 1, 2):
image
where Yi is the output of good i, R is the stock of the public intermediate good, and Li is the labor input in sector i. From this formulation, it is clear that labor productivity in private sector i is exhibited by Ai(R) and is dependent on the stock of the public intermediate good R. We make the following assumption for Ai(R):
image
The production function of the public sector is expressed as G=f(LR), where LR is a labor input in the public sector. Concerning f(LR), we assume that
image
The accumulation of the public intermediate good is described in the following dynamic equation:
image(1)
where β > 0 is the depreciation rate of the stock of the public intermediate good.
At each moment in time, the economy must face the following full employment constraint on labor:
image
where L > 0 is labor endowment and is assumed to be given and constant over time. With this constraint and using private production functions, we obtain the PPF for a given LR and R as
image(2)
Now we turn our attention to the behavior of a representative household. The lifetime utility of a representative household is given by
image(3)
where Ci is consumption of good i, ρ > 0 is the rate of time preference, and α∈ (0, 1) is a parameter.
The home government determines inline image to maximize (3) subject to (1), (2), and its balance of payments
image(4)
where p is the world price of good 1 relative to that of good 2 and is assumed to be given and constant over time.
The current-value Hamiltonian function is described as
image
Then, the optimal controls must satisfy
image(5)
image(6)
image(7)
Moreover, the adjoint equation and the transversality condition are, respectively, expressed as
image(8)
image
In view of (4), (5), (6), and (7), the following condition holds along the optimal path:
image(9)

3. dynamic system

In this section, we inspect the properties of a dynamic system. Defining the production elasticity of the public intermediate good stock in sector i as inline image, we make the following assumption regarding the impact of the public intermediate good on industries:

Assumption 1 η1(R) > η2(R).

The above assumption implies that the public intermediate good serves more significantly in the production in sector 1 than in that of sector 2.

Let inline image be a function satisfying the relation of p=A2(R)/A1(R). Then, inline image is decreasing in p under Assumption 1.

Considering (6), we can confirm that, if inline image, the economy is specialized in producing good 2, whereas if inline image, the economy is specialized in producing good 1. Thus, substituting (2), (7), and (9) into (8), we obtain the following Euler equation:
image(10)
According to (10), we can verify that the locus of inline image has a “reversed N” shape, as illustrated in the following figures. The dynamic movement of θ according to (10) under a given R is as follows: Above the inline image locus, θ must increase and below the locus, θ must decrease.
Letting LR=λ (θ, L) express the relation of (9), we have
image
Replacing LR with λ (θ, L), we can rewrite (1) as
image(11)
According to (11), it is easily verified that the locus of inline image is upward sloping and that the amount of the public good stock must decrease in the upper area and increase in the lower area of the locus. Moreover, the locus is affected by the level of L such that an increase in L shifts the inline image locus downward and vice versa.

In sum, we obtain a dynamic system of θ and R in the small open economy as described by (10) and (11).

4. pattern of specialization

We now investigate the steady state of the dynamic system constructed by (10) and (11). The steady state is a point (R*, θ*) satisfying inline image. Let inline image be a solution of inline image, and consider the following three cases separately:

  • Case 1: inline image,

  • Case 2: inline image,

  • Case 3: inline image.

In Case 1, a unique steady state where the economy specializes in good 1 exists and is saddle-point stable. This case occurs when inline image is sufficiently large and/or p is adequately high. If, in addition, inline image and inline image are sufficiently close to each other, the steady state is globally saddle-point stable. This particular case is displayed in Figure 1, where the gap between points A and B becomes sufficiently small and thus a global saddle path can exist.

Details are in the caption following the image


unique and globally saddle-point stable steady state in case 1: (inline image)

In order to see the production pattern on the global saddle path, we suppose in Figure 1 that the initial point is C, where inline image. Thus, starting at R0, R gradually approaches the steady state E along the saddle path. Then, only good 2 is produced until R reaches inline image. Once R reaches inline image, the economy diversifies in production, and after R exceeds inline image, only good 1 is produced.

In Case 2, where a unique steady state exists, the economy specializes in good 2 and the steady state is saddle-point stable. This case appears if L is sufficiently small and/or p is adequately low. Because this case becomes the reverse of Case 1, we omit the figure. Again, if inline image and inline image are sufficiently close to each other, the steady state becomes globally saddle-point stable.

Concerning the production pattern on the global saddle path, we suppose that the initial stock is given by inline image. Starting at R0, R gradually approaches the steady state along the saddle path. Then, the production pattern of this economy becomes the opposite of Case 1 with respect to time path, implying that production is first specialized in good 2, then diversified at inline image, and finally specialized again, but in good 1 after R exceeds inline image.

Finally, we consider Case 3. In this case, three steady states, E1, E2, and Ed, exist, as shown in Figure 2.E1 and E2 are locally saddle-point stable, whereas Ed is unstable. At E1 and E2, the economy is specialized in goods 1 and 2, respectively. Both goods are produced at the unstable steady state Ed.

Details are in the caption following the image


multiple steady states in case 3: (inline image)

In this case, the initial level of R determines the steady-state specialization pattern: If inline image, the steady state is E1 and production is specialized in good 1, whereas if inline image, the steady state is E2 and production is specialized in good 2.

Now we summarize the results obtained in this section as the following theorem:

Theorem 1 If L is sufficiently large and/or p is adequately high to satisfy the condition that inline image, there exists a unique saddle-point stable steady state where the economy is specialized in good 1. IfLis sufficiently small and/orpis adequately low to satisfy the condition thatinline image, there exists a unique saddle-point stable steady state where the economy is specialized in good 2. Otherwise, three steady states appear, two of which are saddle-point stable and one of which, with diversified production, is unstable. In this case, if the initial stock of the public intermediate good is less [resp. greater] thaninline image, specialization occurs in good 2 [resp. good 1] in the steady state.

McMillan (1978) asserted in his Proposition 3 that a unique steady state necessarily exists. Although our model is a special case of McMillan (1978), it shows the possibility of two saddle-point stable steady states. This particularly occurs in the case where the size of labor endowment and the level of the consumption-good price ratio are moderate. In this case, which steady state is finally realized relies on the initial level of the public intermediate good stock. If the initial stock level is sufficiently high [low], a country can have an advantage in the industry whose productivity is more [less] sensitive to the amount of public intermediate good stock. Thus, the country tends to specialize in the commodity of this industry.

The difference between our and McMillan's results is due to the fact that McMillan disregarded the nonsmoothness property of the inline image curve at the incomplete specialization point. Moreover, McMillan considered the phase where the public intermediate good is not produced. However, in our analysis, such a phase never occurs, implying that the public intermediate good is produced at all points of time.

5. transition from autarky to free trade

We examined the pattern of production at a steady state in a small trading country. Advancing our analysis, we now investigate how the production pattern varies along the time path starting from the autarkic steady-state equilibrium as an initial position. For this purpose, let us derive the autarkic equilibrium of this economy.

The home government's problem under autarky is to maximize (3) subject to (1), (2), and relevant market clearing conditions
image(12)
The current-value Hamiltonian function is described as
image
Then, the optimality conditions are
image
Moreover, the adjoint equation is
image
Using (12) and the optimal conditions, the above adjoint equation can be rewritten as
image(13)
where h(R) ≡αη1(R) + (1 −α)η2(R).

Thus, the dynamic system of a closed economy is built by dynamic equations (11) and (13). Because the locus of inline image is a convex combination of θ=η1(R)/[(ρ+β)R] and θ=η2(R)/[(ρ+β)R], the locus is monotonically downward sloping. As in the case of free trade, the locus of inline image is drawn as a monotonically upward-sloping curve. Therefore, there exists a unique autarkic steady state denoted by inline image.

We consider a transition from autarky to free trade and investigate how a country's welfare changes by this transition. We assume that the economy is initially in a steady state. Then, if inline image (we refer to this case as Case I), the country has a comparative advantage in good 1. This is because the autarkic steady-state price pa satisfies the condition that inline image, and inline image is a decreasing function of p. Thus, the autarkic steady-state price pa is lower than the international price p.

Figure 3 illustrates the transition from autarky to free trade in Case I, where E and Ea in the figure are the steady states under free trade and autarky, respectively. As is clear from this figure, Case I occurs when the labor endowment is sufficiently large so that inline image holds.

Details are in the caption following the image


transition from autarky to free trade: case I (inline image)

Likewise, if inline image (we refer to this as Case II), the country has a comparative advantage in good 2. This case occurs when labor endowment is sufficiently small so that inline image holds. The transition from autarky to free trade corresponding to this case can be shown diagrammatically in a fashion similar to Case I, and thus we omit the figure.

In sum, we assert

Theorem 2 Suppose that the country is initially in an autarkic steady state. Then, after opening trade, if the country faces a higher [resp. lower] international relative price of good 1 than its autarkic steady-state relative price, the country specializes in good 1 [resp. good 2] at the steady state under free trade, as well as during the entire period of reaching the steady state.

McMillan (1978) did not investigate the transition path from the autarkic steady state to the free-trade steady state after the opening of trade. The above theorem shows that changes in the pattern of specialization never occur along any transition path from autarky to a free-trade steady state.

6. gains from trade

In the previous section, we inspected the autarkic steady-state equilibrium. Using this result, we investigate whether trade is gainful or harmful at the steady state. Let us first present the following lemma:

Lemma 1 Suppose that the economy specializes in good i under free trade ( i= 1, 2 ). Then, evaluated at the steady state, Ai(R)(LLR) is increasing in R .

Proof From (1), dLR/dR=β/f′ (LR) holds in the steady state. Using this and (9), we have
image
In light of (10), which indicates that inline image holds in the steady state, the numerator of the above expression is positive.                   ▪

Now we investigate whether a small open economy gains or loses from trade at the steady state. We separately consider the two cases examined in the previous section.

Case I. inline image.

In this case, it must hold that inline image. Given this and Lemma 1, it holds that inline image, i= 1, 2. This implies that the long-run PPF expands after trade. Moreover, because p > A2(R*)/A1(R*), the trading line (with slopep) of the economy specializing in good 1 is drawn outside the long-run PPF under free trade. Comparing the steady-state consumption point under autarky, which is on the autarkic long-run PPF, and the steady-state consumption point under free trade, which is on the trading line, it follows that the steady-state welfare level is higher under free trade than under autarky. In other words, the economy unambiguously gains from trade at the steady state in this case.

Case II. inline image.

In this case, we have inline image. Given this and Lemma 1, it is observed that the long-run PPF contracts after trade. This case is illustrated in Figure 4, where the downward straight line closer to the origin exhibits the long-run PPF under free trade, whereas the other downward straight line is that of autarky.

Details are in the caption following the image

the gains or losses from trade in case II

In contrast to Case I, the trading line and the long-run PPF intersect in this case. This means that, depending on preferences, the economy may gain or lose from trade at the steady state. For example, if the autarkic steady-state equilibrium pair of consumption is given by point A1 in Figure 4, trade enhances welfare at the steady state. On the other hand, if the autarkic steady state is on A2, trade reduces welfare at the steady state.

Now we establish the following theorem:

Theorem 3 If inline image, trade is unambiguously gainful at the steady state. However, ifinline image, trade is possibly harmful at the steady state.

As seen in Figure 4, the possibility of trade losses is caused by a shrinkage of the long-run PPF. This is the result of a long-run decrease in the stock of a public intermediate good caused by the opening of trade. This case must appear in a country that has an advantage in the good with less sensitive productivity of the public intermediate good, and thus in a country with a small labor endowment.

Note that in the present analysis of gains from trade, we focus only on the steady state. Thus, we show the possibility of trade losses at the steady state. In the case of the entire period encompassing the transition to the steady state, this possibility of trade losses may not disappear. To make a complete analysis, we also need to compare the transition path of a closed economy with that of an open economy.

7. summary and remarks

In this study, we reexamined McMillan's (1978) analysis of trade patterns and added the gains-from-trade analysis of a small Ricardian economy in a dynamic framework. Our investigation into the patterns of trade presented the following results. If the labor endowment is sufficiently large (small), a small open country specializes in a good whose productivity is more (less) sensitive to the public intermediate good in the long run. In the case where the sensitivity of the productivity to the public intermediate good stock is similar between private industries, a switch in trade patterns along the dynamic path can occur. This possibility of a switch is not properly presented in McMillan (1978), even though the model is essentially the same. Moreover, we demonstrated that, if the labor endowment is of intermediate size, there are two saddle-point stable long-run equilibria, and the initial stock of the public intermediate good determines the long-run trade patterns according to the history-dependent time paths. This aspect was also overlooked in McMillan's analysis.

Concerning trade gains, we obtained the following results. If a country enjoys a comparative advantage in producing a good whose output is more responsive to the stock of a public intermediate good, the economy unambiguously gains from trade at the steady state. In contrast, if a country enjoys a comparative advantage in producing a good whose output is less responsive to the public intermediate good stock, the economy may lose from trade.

We need to extend our present analysis of the Ricardian type to that of the non-Ricardian type. In a two-factor case like the Heckscher–Ohlin model, if we assume that public or private capital can be accumulated, the factor endowment ratio varies from time to time. Therefore, the theorems depending on the factor endowment ratio may be seriously affected in a dynamic trade model. Of another importance is to treat the present issue in a two-country dynamic framework. Thus, we need to handle the two state variables, each of which is a public intermediate good stock specific to the country. Then the model becomes that of a dynamic game. Finally, though we focused on public goods serving private production, it may be interesting to consider the role of public consumption goods in international trade. In fact, Connolly (1970) treated an international trade analysis in a static two-country framework with public consumption good long time ago. However, the dynamic analysis still remains in this case.

Footnotes

  • 2 According to Meade's (1952) clarification, there are two types of public intermediate goods. One is the type of “creation of atmosphere,” where a public intermediate good is available without congestion. The other is the type of “unpaid factor,” where congestion arises within an industry but not between industries in the use of a public intermediate good. In this study, we consider the former type. See also Feehan (1989) for further discussions on types of public intermediate goods.
  • 3 McMillan (1978) presents each private sector's production function in a general form: Yi=Fi(Li, R). However, he assumed inline image, which is reduced to our specification.
  • 4 In McMillan (1978), the dynamics of R is given by inline image, and two specifications of the function FR(LR, R) are made. Our specification is the same as McMillan's first case, and his second case is FR(LR, R) =H(LR, R) −βR, where H(LR, R) is increasing and concave in R. In this second case, multiple steady states can exist, as shown by McMillan (1978). However, as we will demonstrate in the following analysis, multiple steady states are possible even under McMillan's first specification.
  • 5 Here, we implicitly assume that households have no assets and that the public intermediate good stock is owned by the government and is available free to any private firm.
  • 6 Therefore, this is a type of social planning problem, but its outcome can coincide with the market outcome as long as the government supplies the public intermediate good with optimal income taxes in a manner similar to that in Manning et al. (1985) or Feehan and Matsumoto (2000).
  • 7 As will be seen in the following analysis, any time path (θ(t), R(t)) to reach steady states is finite. Hence, the transversality condition is always satisfied in our setting.
  • 8 If the gap between points A and B is sufficiently large, the saddle-point stability may hold only locally.
  • 9 As a special case, there can be two steady states. This occurs when the inline image locus passes through the top or bottom point on the vertical segment of the inline image locus.
  • 10 We can confirm this by the fact that, concerning Jacobian matrix evaluated at Ed, its trace =ρ > 0 and its determinant inline image.
  • 11 The vertical segment of the inline image locus reflects the knife-edge result in the Ricardian model where production jumps from complete specialization in one good to complete specialization in the other good.
  • 12 We can further divide Case I into the following two subcases:dCase I (a): inline image,Case I (b): inline image.Case I (a) corresponds to a unique steady state in Case 1, whereas Case I (b) corresponds to multiple steady states (i.e., Case 3). In fact, Figure 3 illustrates the transition from autarky to free trade corresponding to Case I (b).
  • 13 As in Case I, we can divide Case II into the following two subcases:Case II (a): inline image,Case II (b): inline image.Case II (a) corresponds to the unique steady state in Case 2, whereas Case II (b) corresponds to multiple steady states (Case 3).
  • 14 We appreciate one of the referees and Professor Murray Kemp for this point.
    • The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.