Volume 20, Issue 1 pp. 177-185
Full Access

Parallel Trade and its Ambiguous Effects on Global Welfare

Frank Mueller-Langer

Corresponding Author

Frank Mueller-Langer

Max Planck Institute for Intellectual Property and Competition Law, Marstallplatz 1, 80539 Munich, Germany

The author wishes to thank an anonymous referee, Monika Schnitzer, Jürgen Eichberger, Klaus Schmidt, Hans-Bernd Schäfer, Eberhard Feess, and colleagues and seminar participants in Hamburg, Heidelberg, Munich, Copenhagen, and Toulouse for their valuable comments.

Mueller-Langer: Max Planck Institute for Intellectual Property and Competition Law, Marstallplatz 1, 80539 Munich, Germany. Tel: +49-89-24246453; Fax: +49-89-24246503; E-mail: [email protected].Search for more papers by this author
First published: 16 January 2012
Citations: 16

Abstract

The regulation of parallel trade is a fiercely debated issue in the global trading system. This paper investigates the welfare effects of parallel trade freedom for different levels of trade costs and market size. It is found that parallel trade freedom has a positive effect on global welfare if countries are sufficiently heterogeneous in terms of market size and trade costs are sufficiently low. Contrary to intuition, this result even holds in a situation where parallel trade freedom implies the closure of the smaller market. If, however, countries are virtually homogenous in terms of market size, parallel trade freedom may be detrimental to global welfare for specific levels of trade costs.

1. Introduction

The regulation of parallel trade is a fiercely debated issue in the global trading system. At the heart of this debate is the ambiguous nature of the welfare effects of parallel trade, an aspect which has been noted by Ganslandt and Maskus (2004), Maskus and Chen (2004), and Valletti and Szymanski (2006). A compromise reached under World Trade Organization (WTO) law permits countries to freely decide whether to allow or ban parallel trade.1 Advocates of strong patent rights for pharmaceuticals support a global policy banning parallel trade. Danzon (1998) argued that if parallel trade of pharmaceuticals were permitted, profits in the pharmaceutical industry would decrease, thereby reducing incentives to invest in research and development (R&D) for new drugs. Grossman and Lai (2008) opposed this argument. Nevertheless, as pointed out by Maskus (2001), policymakers in many developing countries support an open regime of parallel trade and place a greater emphasis on the affordability of pharmaceuticals than on promoting R&D abroad.

Maskus and Ganslandt (2002) put forward that parallel trade freedom may increase prices in low-income countries and result in smaller markets not being served. We will show that this assertion is correct for specific combinations of parallel trade costs and heterogeneity of countries in terms of market size. However, we will also show that in this case parallel trade freedom still exerts a positive effect on global welfare even though small markets remain unserved. This conclusion contrasts with previous work on the welfare effects of parallel trade by Jelovac and Bordoy (2005) and Malueg and Schwartz (1994).2

There are three main strands of literature on the determinants of parallel trade.3 First, Maskus (2000) and Maskus and Chen (2004) suggested that multinational companies build markets through exclusive territorial dealership rights in order to vertically control the operations of their licensees. They may, however, find it difficult to enforce private contractual provisions prohibiting sales outside the authorized distribution chain so that parallel trade occurs. Our study of parallel trade is closely related to this strand of literature. Second, Brekke et al. (2009) and Ganslandt and Maskus (2004) suggested that in certain industries such as the pharmaceutical industry national governments intervene in private markets by regulating prices. As this results in international price differences, there is a potential for arbitrage between markets as put forward by Grossman and Lai (2008) and Richardson (2002). A third determinant of parallel trade, as suggested by Maskus (2000), is the incentive of parallel importing firms to free ride on investments in marketing as well as on the before- and after-sales services of official licensees and authorized distributors.

2. Simple Model of Parallel Trade

We consider a model with two countries, denoted by subscript j = A,B, and two firms. In country A there is a monopolistic manufacturer m. In country B there is a single authorized independent firm r that is responsible for the distribution and retail of the manufacturer's product. We assume that efficient international distribution of the product requires the manufacturer to build a market in B through exclusive territorial dealership rights. Suppose that the exclusive distributor in B has already established costly distribution channels. The demand in A is qA = γa − bpA, and the demand in B is qB = abpB, with γ > 1. Let γ measure the heterogeneity of the two countries in terms of markets size. Let Π denote the profit of the manufacturer and π the profit of the distributor, respectively. For simplicity, we assume that the marginal costs of production are equal to zero in both countries. The exclusive distributor sells to consumers in B at first, but may also engage in parallel trade from B to A. Arbitrage by individual consumers between B and A is legally prohibited. The marginal costs of engaging in parallel trade are denoted by t. They include, following Berka (2009), Li and Maskus (2006), and Maskus and Chen (2004), parallel-trade specific distribution and advertising costs as a result of re-packaging and re-labeling as well as import duties on parallel trade. We assume that the parallel import product is a perfect substitute for the product sold by the original producer in A. We analyze a situation in which the manufacturer is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade as a benchmark.

Double Marginalization without Parallel Trade

Suppose that the manufacturer can become involved in the retail of the product in A. The distributor in B has a monopoly on the local retailing business. We assume that retailing in B does not involve any costs, except for the costs incurred by the distributor in buying the product from the manufacturer. In the first stage, the manufacturer sets a wholesale price inline image for the distributor, who then sets a retail price pB in the second stage. The manufacturer is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade of the product from B, i.e. he is awarded an exclusive importation right. The manufacturer maximizes inline image. The distributor maximizes inline image. We obtain the following equilibrium quantities supplied (inline image) and retail prices (inline image) for the two countries, wholesale price in B (inline image) and profits:
image(1)

Double Marginalization with Parallel Trade

Suppose that the manufacturer cannot prohibit or at least contractually limit parallel trade. In the first stage, the manufacturer chooses the wholesale price inline image, inline image, at which he sells the product to the distributor in B. In the second stage, the distributor chooses the retail price pB, pB ∈ [0, ∞), in B. In the third stage, the manufacturer m and the exclusive distributor r simultaneously choose the prices at which they sell the product in A in a Bertrand model of duopoly, e.g. inline image, inline image, and inline image, inline image, respectively.

Proposition 1. Parallel trade does not occur in any sub-game perfect Nash equilibrium in a double marginalization game with Bertrand price competition in the last stage.

The proof is straightforward as the manufacturer's marginal cost of production is equal to zero and inline image. In the second stage, the distributor anticipates that he will be driven out of the market in A in the third stage. He maximizes the profit generated in B. Working backwards to the first stage and adopting the Kuhn–Tucker method, the maximization problem of the manufacturer is given by:
image(2)
and inline image
We obtain two solutions that satisfy all first-order conditions. First,
image(3)
Note that inline image as t > 0. More specifically, inline image. The higher the parallel trade costs (and thus the less profitable the parallel trade) the higher inline image is and the lower inline image. However, inline image is only satisfied for specific values of the parameter t. From inline image follows inline image. For inline image to be satisfied it is sufficient that inline image. Henceforth, we will refer to th = (a/2b)(γ − 1) as the threshold for high trade costs. To summarize, (inline image, inline image, inline image, inline image, inline image) only satisfies all first-order conditions if t ≤ th. If, however, t > th, it is not a solution for the maximization problem of the manufacturer as given by (2) as inline image in this case.
We obtain the second solution:
image(4)

Note that inline image (inline image) is equal to the monopoly price (profit-maximizing wholesale price) in a double marginalization game in which parallel trade is prohibited. Intuitively, if the two countries are virtually homogeneous (γ → 1) and the parallel trade costs are so high that t > th, the distributor will not be willing to engage in parallel trade.

3. Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom on Profits

There are three types of trade costs, denoted by subscript k = h, i, l. Subscript h denotes high trade costs, t > th, subscript i denotes intermediate trade costs, tl ≤ t ≤ th, and subscript l denotes low trade costs, t < tl. For high trade costs, we obtain the following equilibrium prices and quantities in both countries:
image(5)
For intermediate trade costs, we obtain:
image(6)
As we will see below, for low trade costs, country B will not be served. We obtain the following equilibrium price and quantity in country A:
image(7)

In both situations, with and without parallel trade, equilibrium prices and quantities in countries A and B are identical if t > th. The threshold for low trade costs is denoted by tl. The distributor will only be willing to sell the product in B as long as inline image (inline image). From this follows: inline image. Intuitively, if trade costs are very low, t < tl, potential competition from parallel trade is so fierce that the manufacturer has to charge such a high wholesale price in B in order to deter parallel trade that the distribution of the good in B becomes unprofitable.

To summarize, we consider three scenarios. First, parallel trade costs are so high, t > th, that parallel trade is not a worthwhile activity for the distributor and thus a non-credible threat. Parallel trade freedom then does not have any impact on profits, consumer surplus as well as national and global welfare. Second, the manufacturer strategically sets prices in order to deter parallel trade if tl ≤ t ≤ th. However, the wholesale price will be sufficiently low so that the distribution of the product in B is still a worthwhile activity. Third, the manufacturer will charge such a high wholesale price in B in order to deter parallel trade that the market in B ends up not being served if t < tl.

Effect of Parallel Trade Freedom on the Profit of the Manufacturer

For intermediate and low trade costs, the equilibrium profits of the manufacturer are inline image, andinline imageinline image, respectively, if parallel trade is permitted. If, however, the manufacturer is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade, his profit does not depend on the level of trade costs and is given by Π** = (a2/8b)(2γ2 + 1).

Proposition 2. The threat of parallel trade leads to lower profits for the manufacturer (i) if trade costs are intermediate, or (ii) if trade costs are low.

The proof is straightforward since (i) inline image and (ii) inline image. Intuitively, parallel trade is not a credible threat and does not erode the manufacturer's ability to discriminate prices if t > th. If trade costs are intermediate or low, however, parallel trade is a credible threat and the manufacturer sets prices strategically as a deterrent. According to Lutz (2004), the threat of parallel trade then erodes the manufacturer's ability to discriminate prices and thus reduces his profit as opposed to a situation where he is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade. An important point in favor of banning parallel trade is the following. Under the assumption that an investment in R&D leads with certainty to the development of a new product, the maximum amount the manufacturer is willing to invest ex ante is his expected profit. A ban on parallel trade then leads to higher R&D incentives since the profit of the manufacturer under a ban on parallel trade is higher than that under parallel trade freedom as Valletti and Szymanski (2006) have argued. Hence, if the unique social objective were to spur R&D for new products by protecting the manufacturer, our model suggests that the manufacturer should be awarded the right to prevent parallel trade.

Effect of Parallel Trade Freedom on the Profit of the Distributor

If the manufacturer is awarded the right to prevent parallel trade, or if it is permitted but trade costs are high, the profit of the distributor is given by inline image. If trade costs are intermediate and parallel trade is permitted, the distributor will make a profit according to inline image. Parallel trade freedom is detrimental to the distributor in this case as inline image at its unique maximum tl. The manufacturer will charge a higher wholesale price in country B—as compared with the wholesale price under a ban on parallel trade—in order to deter parallel trade. Hence, the distributor will sell less at a higher price resulting in a lower profit under parallel trade freedom. Finally, inline image if t < tl.

4. Effect of Parallel Trade Freedom on Global Welfare

From the equilibrium prices, quantities, and profits given in section 3, it is straightforward to derive consumer surplus and welfare in both countries if parallel trade is prohibited, and if it is permitted, respectively. We obtain the following levels of global welfare—being the sum of national welfare in A and B—if parallel trade is prohibited (W**), and if it is permitted (inline image):
image(8)

We derive the welfare effects of parallel trade freedom by subtracting global welfare if the manufacturer has the right to prevent parallel trade from global welfare under parallel trade freedom. Recall, however, that even if parallel trade were permitted, the (non-credible) threat of parallel trade would not have any impact on global welfare if t > th.

Welfare Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom for Intermediate Trade Costs

Proposition 3. Parallel trade freedom increases global welfare if trade costs are intermediate and (i) γ ≥ 5/2 or (ii) inline image.

Proof. (i) Let the net effect of parallel trade freedom on global welfare be denoted by ΔWi:
image(9)

Note that ΔWi is a quadratic function of t. Note also that ΔWi = 0 at th = (a/2b)(γ − 1). Hence, in order to show that ΔWi ≥ 0, it is sufficient to show that ΔWi is a monotonically decreasing function of t for tl ≤ t ≤ th. From inline image follows inline image. As inline image is the unique maximum, ΔWi decreases in t for any inline image. Taking into account that ΔWi = 0 at th = (a/2b)(γ − 1), it follows that ΔWi > 0 for inline image. We analyze for which values of γinline image. It is straightforward to see that inline image if γ ≥ 5/2. Furthermore, ΔWi monotonically decreases in t for tl ≤ t ≤ th. Hence, taking into account that ΔWi = 0 at th, ΔWi ≥ 0 if γ ≥ 5/2.

(ii) If γ < 5/2, we cannot apply the same logic as in the previous case as tl = (a/2b)(γ − 5/2) would be negative. Since t is non-negative, we set tl = 0 in this case. For γ < 5/2, ΔWi has its unique maximum at inline image, which is positive as γ < 5/2. Hence, the question arises as to whether ΔWi is positive or negative at tl. If we can show that ΔWi is positive at t = 0, this would imply that ΔWi is also positive for tl ≤ t ≤ th, taking into account that ΔWi = 0 at th. By setting t = 0 in (9) we obtain ΔWi = (a2/72b)(4γ2 − 11γ + 7). Note that ΔWi ≥ 0 if γ ≥ 7/4. Consequently, if γ ≥ 7/4, ΔWi is positive between zero and th. Thus, ΔWi ≥ 0 if 7/4 ≤ γ < 5/2. □

Intuitively, parallel trade freedom harms both the manufacturer as well as the distributor. Parallel trade freedom is also detrimental to consumers in country B because it leads to a higher local retail price and a lower quantity sold. Hence, consumers in country A are the only beneficiaries from parallel trade freedom. As long as γ is sufficiently large, 7/4 ≤ γ, the positive effect of parallel trade freedom on consumers in A ceteris paribus more than outweighs the sum of its negative effects on the manufacturer, the distributor, and consumers in B.

In contrast, Numerical Example 1 illustrates that the following proposition holds.

Proposition 4. Parallel trade freedom can exhibit negative welfare properties if trade costs are intermediate and γ is sufficiently low [1 < γ < 7/4].

Recall that ΔWi = 0 at th = (a/2b)(γ − 1). By looking at (9), it becomes apparent that ΔWi has another null at t = (a/2b)(7/2 − 2γ) > 0 as γ < 7/4.

Numerical Example 1. We set a = 100, b = 1/2 and γ = 13/8.

Figure 1 shows that ΔWi = 0 at t = 25 and at t = th = 62.5. Furthermore, ΔWi has its unique maximum at inline image. Also, tl = 0. We can see from Figure 1 that ΔWi < 0 ∀t ∈ (0, 25), which suggests that Proposition 4 holds. If countries A and B are virtually homogeneous, 1 < γ < 7/4, consumers in A will benefit less from parallel trade freedom. In this case, the effect of parallel trade freedom on global welfare will be negative if trade costs are intermediate.

Details are in the caption following the image

Welfare Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom (a = 100, b = 1/2, and γ = 13/8)

Welfare Effects of Parallel Trade Freedom for Low Trade Costs

Proposition 5. Parallel trade freedom increases global welfare if trade costs are low and γ is sufficiently high, γ > 5/2, even though the smaller market remains unserved.

Proof. For tl > t, the effect of parallel trade freedom on global welfare is:
image(10)

As we can see, ΔWl is a quadratic function of t. Recall that γ must be greater than 5/2 as t > 0. For smaller values of the parameter γ, we would automatically end up in one of the other scenarios mentioned above. By differentiating (10) we obtain inline image. inline image is the unique maximum as inline image. Furthermore, inline image. By setting t = 0 in (10), we obtain ΔWl = (a2/288b)(20γ2 − 16γ − 67). We can see that ΔWl > 0 at t = 0 if γ > 5/2. By setting t = tl = (a/2b)(γ − 5/2) in (10), it follows that ΔWl = (a2/8b)(γ − 2). ΔWl > 0 as γ > 5/2. Consequently, taking into account that ΔWl is a quadratic function of t, inline image, ΔWl > 0 at t = 0, and ΔWl > 0 at tl, it is straightforward to see that ΔWl > 0 if tl > t and inline image. □

Contrary to intuition, parallel trade freedom still has a positive effect on global welfare in this case even though the market in B remains unserved. If γ is sufficiently high, the positive effect of parallel trade freedom on consumers in A ceteris paribus more than outweighs its negative effects associated with lower profits for the manufacturer and the closure of the market in B.

5. Conclusion

Our two-country model of parallel trade based on the work of Maskus and Chen (2004) suggests that the threat of parallel trade can limit the monopolistic manufacturer's scope for price discrimination and thus increase retail-market competition. While this finding is in line with the prior literature on parallel trade, such as Ganslandt and Maskus (2004) and Malueg and Schwartz (1994), we find that the manufacturer's strategic pricing to avert parallel trade depends on the level of heterogeneity of countries in terms of market size and on the level of parallel trade costs. If parallel trade costs are high, potential competition from parallel trade does not arise, and the manufacturer will always charge the monopoly price in the domestic market. If, however, parallel trade costs are low, potential competition from parallel trade arises, and the manufacturer advantageously sets prices in the domestic and foreign market in order to avert parallel trade. In an empirical, policy-oriented article, Maskus and Ganslandt (2002) have put forward that parallel trade may increase prices in low-income countries and lead to the closure of smaller markets. Our analysis confirms this assertion under the condition of low trade costs and sufficient heterogeneity of market size in both countries. Because of the threat of severe competition from parallel trade, the manufacturer sets a prohibitively high wholesale price in the foreign market resulting in unprofitable product distribution abroad. Consequently, it would be desirable for policymakers in the foreign country to discourage parallel trade and to encourage price discrimination in order to open the otherwise unserved market. Nevertheless, we also show that even in this case global welfare is positively affected through parallel trade freedom. It is in this respect that we believe our analysis is different from existing works such as Maskus and Chen (2004), Valletti (2006), and Valletti and Szymanski (2006).

As to the general welfare properties of parallel trade freedom, it increases global welfare if countries are sufficiently heterogeneous in terms of market size. Yet, for intermediate trade costs and virtually homogeneous countries, parallel trade freedom can have negative welfare properties. In this case, the negative effect on the manufacturer, the distributor, as well as on consumers in the foreign country more than outweighs the positive effect of parallel trade freedom on domestic consumers. Considering these ambiguous welfare effects, we suggest that neither parallel trade freedom nor a ban, but instead a rule of reason is justified from an economic perspective.

Notes

  • 1 Article 6 of the WTO Agreement on Trade-related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS Agreement) excludes the treatment of parallel trade from dispute settlement and preserves the territorial privilege for regulating parallel trade.
  • 2 Malueg and Schwartz (1994) found that global welfare under parallel trade freedom will be lower than under international price discrimination if parallel trade freedom implies that some markets are dropped.
  • 3 Recent work, such as Li and Maskus (2006), Li and Robles (2007), Valletti (2006), and Valletti and Szymanski (2006), also analyzed the dynamic effects of parallel trade on R&D.
    • The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.