Volume 50, Issue 3 pp. 481-510
Full Access

Determinants of executive compensation in privately held firms

Jesper Banghøj

Jesper Banghøj

Department of Accounting and Auditing

Search for more papers by this author
Gorm Gabrielsen

Gorm Gabrielsen

Center for Statistics, Copenhagen Business School, DK-2000 Frederiksberg, Denmark

Search for more papers by this author
Christian Petersen

Christian Petersen

Department of Accounting and Auditing

Search for more papers by this author
Thomas Plenborg

Thomas Plenborg

Department of Accounting and Auditing

Search for more papers by this author
First published: 17 August 2010
Citations: 29

We acknowledge the helpful comments of workshop participants at Copenhagen Business School and the EAA congress 2008 in Rotterdam.

Abstract

We examine what determines executive compensation in privately held firms. Our study is motivated by the fact that most studies in this area rely on data from publicly traded firms. Further, the few studies that are based on data from privately held firms only examine a limited number of determinants of executive compensation. Our findings indicate that the pay-to-performance relation is weak. Board size and ownership concentration are the only corporate governance characteristics that explain variations in executive compensation. Executive characteristics like skills, title and educational attainment all explain variations in executive compensation. Contrary to our expectations, we do not find a stronger pay-to-performance relation in firms with better designed bonus plans.

1. Introduction

The compensation of chief executive officers (CEOs) is a topic of great interest to both academics and practitioners. A considerable number of papers have examined what explains the level of executive compensation. With a few exceptions, these studies are based on data from publicly traded firms (Cole and Mehran, 2008). We add to the literature by examining what explains the level of executive compensation among privately held firms. We analyse a comprehensive set of determinants of executive compensation. Further, as a unique feature of our data set, we are able to evaluate the quality of each executive’s bonus plan. We are, therefore, able to explore whether the expected positive pay-to-performance relation is stronger for better designed bonus plans.

The majority of papers which examine the determinants of executive compensation rely on publicly available data from listed companies. For example, Ke et al. (1999) argue that published studies on compensation in privately held firms are ‘essentially nonexistent because the data generally have not been accessible’. Cole and Mehran (2008) note that with a few exceptions, previous research on executive compensation focus on publicly traded companies that are required to file information on compensation with regulators. However, privately held firms have characteristics that deviate from listed firms and therefore may affect the design of compensation contracts. First, the corporate governance structure of privately held and publicly traded firms deviates. For example, the level of ownership concentration tends to be high in privately held firms as opposed to the often diffuse ownership structure of publicly traded firms (Ke et al., 1999). Thus, owners in privately held firms have better economic incentives to monitor the actions taken by executives (Fama and Jensen, 1983). They also have better access to executives. These elements therefore tend to reduce the need for performance-related compensation, and owners of privately held firms should be more likely to employ a forcing contract with penalty of firing (Ke et al., 1999). On the other hand, there is a tendency that CEOs in privately held firms are more frequently member of the supervisory board than CEOs in publicly traded firms. For example, we find that 34.4 per cent of the CEOs in privately held firms are members of the supervisory board. In comparison, only 17.6 per cent of the CEOs in publicly traded firms in Denmark are members of the supervisory board. This will reduce the board’s independence and may lead to inefficient compensation contracts. Second, Ball and Shivakumar (2005) find that earnings is a relatively more noisy measure of performance in privately held firms than in publicly traded firms. This implies that the pay-to-performance relation is relatively more distorted for privately held firms than for publicly traded firms. Third, as quoted share prices are not available for privately held firms, it is likely that an executive compensation contract in a privately held firm emphasizes fixed salary at the expense of performance-related pay. In summary, privately held firms have characteristics that deviate from listed firms, which may affect both the design of compensation contract and the level of pay.

In Denmark more than 99 per cent of all firms are privately held. A similar high level of privately held firms can be found in most other countries. Given that most firms are privately held it is surprising how little information on executive compensation is available on these firms. Such studies could provide useful information that can be used to design better contracts and would obviously be of interest to executives, board members and shareholders. In a broader context, it is important to gain an understanding of executive compensation and how it affects performance in privately held firms given their dominating role in most economies. It is also essential to examine how factors such as board characteristics, ownership structures, and executive characteristics affect the design of compensation plans. Ultimately, firms with well-designed compensation plans arguably generate more wealth to the society.

The few studies on privately held firms that examine determinants of executive compensation include a few explanatory variables only. As noted in Cole and Mehran (2008) data availability limits the number of testable hypotheses. Even studies that rely on publicly traded firms tend to focus on one or two groups of characteristics only. For example, Core et al. (1999) explore performance, board characteristics and ownership structures ignoring executive characteristics. Cole and Mehran (2008), on the other hand, look at executive characteristics and ownership structures but ignore performance and board characteristics. Examination of just a few characteristics in isolation ignores the fact that other non-measured characteristics may serve as complements or substitutes. Given the level of detail in the data we obtained from our survey, we are able to include a wide list of determinants which are expected to explain executive compensation. In addition to performance and board characteristics, we include executive characteristics such as ownership, education, executive position and tenure. Finally, we include an indicator variable for the quality of the bonus plan as noted below. To our knowledge, this study is the most comprehensive study examining the determinants of executive compensation in privately held firms so far.

Previous studies that explore the pay-to-performance relation assume that the quality of compensation contracts is identical across executives. By contrast, we have detailed information on the design of bonus plans that allows us to rank them based on four unique characteristics. First, we consider bonus plans that rely on more than just one performance measure to be of higher quality than bonus plans that rely on only one performance measure. For example, Feltham and Xie (1994) argue that most performance measures are incomplete or imperfect representations of the economic consequences of management actions. They recommend the use of more than just one performance measure, unless the performance measure is perfectly congruent and noiseless. Second, bonus plans that specifically consider the impact of both transitory items and changes in accounting policies on the performance measures adopted are believed to be of higher quality than bonus plans that ignore these issues. Third, Murphy (2000) finds that income smoothing is prevalent in companies using internal standards (e.g. budget or last year’s financial results) but not in companies using external standards. Thus, bonus plans based on external standards are considered to be of higher quality than bonus plans that rely on internal performance standards. Finally, Healy (1985) and Holmstrom and Milgrom (1987) suggest that the pay-to-performance structure is linear as it mitigates the incentive to manage the performance measure. Thus, linear bonus plans with no cap or floor are considered to be of higher quality than other bonus plans. In conclusion, we conjecture that bonus plans that include the above features are better designed and more accurately capture value creation. Such bonus plans should improve the pay-to-performance relation as well. Murphy (1999) argues that more research is required to better understand the design of accounting-based bonuses. By carefully studying the design of each bonus plan, as outlined above, we believe that we meet this request.

Most studies on executive compensation are based on either UK or US data. A comparison of the Danish and the UK and the US institutional settings reveals several differences that may affect what determines executive compensation. First, Firth et al. (1996) argue that Scandinavian countries (including Denmark) generally have a low variability in wage levels compared with other European countries and the USA. Further, they conjecture that the lack of large differences in pay levels in the Scandinavian countries may be due to the state welfare philosophy, its tax system and the power of the trade unions. The low variability in compensation suggests that performance-related pay is less frequently used or the resulting pay-offs are small in magnitude. Second, the institutional setting in Denmark is characterized by a small open economy with a relationship-oriented corporate governance system, i.e. insider oriented (Eriksson and Lausten, 2000). This tends to reduce the information asymmetry and therefore the need for performance-related pay. Third, Pedersen and Thomsen (1996) document that the existence of dual stock classes in Denmark is related to a higher level of shareholder concentration than in the UK and the USA. The high level of ownership concentration leads us to believe that shareholders’ monitoring of management plays a larger role in Denmark than in the UK and the USA. We conjecture that the monitoring mechanism will reduce the need for performance-related pay. Fourth, Denmark has a two-tier board structure as opposed to the one-tier board structure in the UK and the USA. Fourth, in Denmark CEOs are allowed to serve on the supervisory board but not as board chairman. This is in contrast to, for example, the UK and the USA, where CEOs are also allowed to serve as the board chairman. These differences imply different board compositions across countries. For example, it is arguably less common to find an executive on a Danish board. Fifth, the degree to which an executive can influence board members is most likely smaller in Denmark than in the UK and the USA, where executives also serve as board chairmen. In summary, we conjecture that the institutional differences may impact what determines variations in executive compensation in privately held firms in Denmark.

As compensation data are not publicly available in Denmark, we collected the data through a questionnaire. Eventually 191 respondents completed the questionnaire. However, some respondents did not fill in the questionnaire in full, leaving a final sample of 125 observations. Our data on compensation include insightful information on the various components of executives’ compensation contracts.

Our results provide some interesting insights as to what explains executives’ compensation in privately held firms. In line with our predictions, we find that the pay-to-performance relation is weak. Board size and ownership concentration are the only corporate governance characteristics that explain variations in executive compensation. Executive characteristics like skills (size), executive position and educational attainment all explain variations in executive compensation. Finally, we do not find a stronger pay-to-performance relation in firms with better designed bonus plans.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The next section develops our research hypotheses. In the third section the sample is described followed by a section outlining the research design. The descriptive statistics are provided in the fifth section, followed by the empirical results and robustness checks. Conclusions and suggestions for future research appear in the final section.

2. Research hypotheses

The compensation literature has expanded considerably over the last decade with an increasing number of studies trying to explain the level of compensation. In the following, we list a number of determinants that are likely to elucidate the cross-sectional variation in executive compensation.

2.1. Pay-to-performance relation

Compensation is often seen as an instrument to align managerial interests (agents) with those of the shareholders (principals). The basic idea is to reward executives according to their performance. A vast number of studies have explored the pay-to-performance relation. In their seminal work Jensen and Murphy (1990) find that executive wealth in the US increases by $3.25 for every $1000 increase in shareholder wealth. They conclude that this increase is low. Hall and Liebman (1998) find a strong link between the fortunes of US executives and the fortunes of the firms they manage.

Studies outside the USA document that the pay-to-performance relation is low or even negative. Zhou (1999) compares the pay-to-performance relationship in the USA and Canada. He finds that the pay-to-performance sensitivity is considerably higher in the USA than in Canada. Conyon and Murphy (2000) find that the US executive receives 4.18 per cent of any increase in shareholder wealth compared with 2.33 per cent in the UK. A range of other UK studies also find positive but low pay-to-performance relations (Main et al., 1996; McKnight and Tomkins, 1999; Buck et al., 2003). Brunello et al. (2001) on Italian data, Eriksson and Lausten (2000) on Danish data, Kato and Kubo (2003) on Japanese data and Kato et al. (2004) on Korean data all find positive but low pay-to-performance relations. Analysing a sample of Norwegian and Swedish firms, Randhøy and Nielsen (2002) do not find any link between pay and performance. Fernandes (2008) reaches a similar conclusion based on a sample of Portuguese firms. Finally, based on Dutch firms Duffheus and Kabir (2007) find a negative pay-to-performance relation. Thus, although most studies find a positive pay-to-performance relation, it seems low in most cases.

We conjecture that the pay-to-performance relation is weak based on data from Danish privately held firms. First, while privately held firms are often characterized by high levels of ownership concentration, publicly traded firms have more diffused ownership structures. Thus, owners in privately held firms have better incentives to monitor the actions of the executives reducing the need for performance-related compensation. Second, as mentioned in the Introduction, factors such as the relationship-oriented corporate governance system and the low variability in wage levels in Denmark, compared with other European countries and the USA, reduce the use of performance-related pay. Third, privately held firms are typically small relative to publicly traded firms and most likely less sophisticated in using performance-related pay. Finally, Ball and Shivakumar (2005) find that earnings is a relatively more noisy measure of performance in privately held firms than in publicly traded firms. If earnings is a noisy measure of performance, the pay-to-performance relation will be distorted. All these factors are expected to weaken the pay-to-performance relation for privately held firms.

Hypothesis 1: There is a positive but weak relation between firm performance and executive compensation.

2.2. Corporate governance characteristics

The literature on corporate governance examines the efficiency of alternative board characteristics and ownership structures. For example, Jensen (1993) argues that supervisory boards are ineffective when there is little equity ownership represented on the board, the CEO and the board chair is the same person and if the CEO determines the agenda and the material presented at board meetings. In the compensation literature, corporate governance parameters have been used to explain variations in executive compensation. The basic idea is that inefficient corporate governance structures lead to excessive executive compensation. Core et al. (1999) argue that no board characteristics and ownership structure would be significant in a setting where the executive’s compensation contract specifies the level of compensation as a function of the firm’s performance in order to maximize firm value, conditional of the firm’s informational environment and its demand for high-quality executives. In this setting, the board characteristics and ownership structure are simply ‘noisy measures’ of the same variables that determine executive compensation. However, in a setting where the compensation contract is not optimally designed, board characteristics and ownership structures are expected to affect the level of executive compensation. We explore different board characteristics and ownership structures that may affect the level of executive compensation.

Large supervisory boards are likely to have a wider level of expertise. However, they can become so unwieldy that they become ineffective in monitoring executives (Jensen, 1993). Jensen (1993) points out that when the board exceeds seven or eight members, they are less likely to function effectively and are easier for an executive to control. Yermack (1996) demonstrates how smaller boards are effective in enhancing firm performance. Holthausen and Larcker (1993) and Core et al. (1999) find that large US boards are associated with excessive compensation. These results are obtained in a one-tier board structure setting. As Denmark (and other Scandinavian countries) has a two-tier board structure, the impact of the supervisory board may be different. However, Randhøy and Nielsen (2002) find similar results based on Norwegian and Swedish data. Thus, it indicates that there exists a positive relation between board size and the level of compensation in settings characterized by both a one-tier and two-tier board systems.

Hypothesis 2a: There is a positive relation between board size and executive compensation.

Pfeffer (1981) argues that inside board members are more loyal to management. This implies that executives can exert relatively more influence over inside board members as opposed to outside board members. However, empirical findings by Core et al. (1999) indicate that the relation between executive compensation and percentage of inside directors is negative. These results suggest that theory and empirical evidence are not in line. We examine whether there is a positive relation between the percentage of inside board members and the level of executive compensation in privately held firms.

Hypothesis 2b: There is a positive relation between the percentage of inside board members and executive compensation.

Finkelstein and D’Aveni (1994) argue that a separate management structure will lead to a greater degree of independence to the board in various issues related to monitoring managerial performance. It is expected that boards that have an independent chairman will be more effective in designing a compensation contract and monitoring the performance of management. This also implies that if the executive serves on the board, the independency of the board is reduced and it may affect, among other things, the design of an effective compensation contract. Core et al. (1999) and Iyengar et al. (2005) confirm these predictions. They find that compensation levels are higher in firms where the executive is also the board chair. On the other hand, Angbazo and Narayanan (1997) and Conyon (1997) find no such relation in their study of US and British firms, respectively. In Denmark, an executive is not allowed to serve as chairman of the board. However, an executive may serve as an ordinary board member. Even though the power of an executive as an ordinary board member is not equivalent to the power of the board chairman, we conjecture that the board’s independence is reduced to an extent that may lead to inefficient compensation contracts. This implies that compensation contracts may compensate executives excessively.

Hypothesis 2c: The level of compensation is higher in firms where the executive also serves on the board.

As noted in the Introduction, the level of ownership concentration tends to be high in privately held firms as opposed to the often diffuse ownership structure of publicly traded firms. This provides owners in privately held firms with better economic incentives to monitor the actions taken by executives (Fama and Jensen, 1983). They also have better access to executives. These factors reduce the need for performance-related pay. Several studies confirm this prediction. For example, Core et al. (1999) and Haid and Yurtoglu (2006) find a negative association between the level of ownership concentration and executive compensation based on US and German data, respectively. We also examine whether the association between ownership concentration and executive compensation is negative in privately held firms.

Hypothesis 2d: The level of executive compensation is lower in firms with a high level of ownership concentration.

2.3. Executive characteristics

We explore the impact of executive characteristics on the level of executive compensation. We investigate five types of executive characteristics that may affect the level of executive compensation (hypotheses 3a–e).

One source of executive power is long tenure (Hill and Phan, 1991). Long tenure increases the chances that executives influence the selection of (some) board members. Further, long tenure also ensures stronger relationships with board members. Thus, tenure may explain the level of executive compensation. The empirical evidence on the tenure hypothesis is mixed. Finkelstein and Hambrick (1989) find a curve–linear relation between executive tenure and compensation. Attaway (2000) finds a positive association. O’Reilly et al. (1988), on the other hand, find a negative association. Finally, Randhøy and Nielsen (2002) find no association between tenure and the level of pay. Thus, previous empirical studies do not provide conclusive evidence in support of the tenure hypothesis. We examine the impact of tenure on executive compensation in privately held firms.

Hypothesis 3a: There is a positive association between executive tenure and executive compensation.

Larger and more complex organizations are more difficult to manage and therefore also attract better performing executives. For example, Jensen and Meckling (1976) theorize that the largest firms hire the better performing executives to maximize their productivity. Oetomo and Swan (2003) find that firm size is a partial proxy for managerial ability. Previous studies provide strong evidence in favour of the size hypothesis. Kaplan (1994) on Japanese data, Conyon and Murphy (2000) on UK and US data, Brunello et al. (2001) on Italian data, Zhou (2000) on Canadian data and Haid and Yurtoglu (2006) on German data all find a positive and significant association between executives’ pay and firm size. In fact, in a meta-analysis, Tosi et al. (2000) conclude that firm size accounts for more than 40 per cent of the variance in executive pay, while firm performance accounts for less than 5 per cent. We, therefore, expect a positive association between executives’ pay and firm size.

Hypothesis 3b: There is a positive relation between firm size and executive compensation.

The CEO has the overall responsibility of a firm’s performance. This also explains the number of papers examining the relation between performance and CEO compensation. Although other executives (non-CEOs) such as the chief financial officer (CFO) and the chief developing officer are responsible for the performance of the company too, they will not have the same opportunities to affect the business as the CEO. Further, the level of responsibility is not the same as for the CEO. Thus, the pay-to-performance relation is expected to vary across different hierarchical levels. Murphy (1985) finds no differences in the pay-to-performance relation between CEOs, presidents and vice presidents. Eriksson and Lausten (2000), on the other hand, find small differences in the pay-to-performance relation across different management levels based on Danish data. We conjecture that the pay-to-performance relation is weaker for non-CEOs than for CEOs.

Hypothesis 3c: The pay-to-performance relation is weaker for non-CEOs than for CEOs.

Companies characterized by a high level of managerial ownership already align the interests of the principal and agent. Executives who own shares in their companies have, therefore, a lesser need for direct compensation as they receive dividends and capital gains from their shareholdings. Lower direct compensation may also signal fiscal responsibility by the executive owners (Ramaswamy et al., 2000). Hall and Liebman (1998) and Banghøj and Plenborg (2008) document that managerial ownership is more important than stock options and cash pay as a managerial incentive. Thus, in a Danish setting, where managerial ownership is more common than in the UK and the USA (Conyon and Murphy, 2000; Gabrielsen et al., 2002), we believe that it is important to include executives’ stock holdings when explaining the level of executive compensation. A number of studies examine the association between managerial ownership and the level of executive compensation. Core et al. (1999) find that executive compensation in the USA is a decreasing function of the executive’s ownership stake. Randhøy and Nielsen (2002) on both Norwegian and Swedish data, and Cheng and Firth (2005) on Hong Kong data find similar results.

Hypothesis 3d: Executive compensation is a decreasing function of the executive’s ownership stake.

There are reasons to believe that executive compensation may be a function of educational skills. Based on publicly traded data, Chung and Pruitt (1996) find a positive, although insignificant, association between educational attainment and executive pay. Cole and Mehran (2008) find a positive and significant association between the level of education and executive pay in privately held firms. This indicates that there exists a positive association between educational attainment and executive compensation.

Hypothesis 3e: There is a positive relation between educational attainment and executive compensation.

2.4. Quality of bonus plan

To our knowledge, previous studies that explore the pay-to-performance relation assume that the quality of bonus plans is identical across executives. We challenge this view by arguing that the pay-to-performance relation is a function of the quality of the bonus plan. Inspired by Murphy (1999) we list four areas that need to be addressed when designing a bonus plan. First, the board needs to decide on an appropriate performance measure. Feltham and Xie (1994) point out that the literature has paid only limited attention to the fact that performance measures are frequently incomplete or imperfect representations of the economic consequences of the manager’s action. Thus, the choice of performance measure is not obvious. Feltham and Xie recommend the use of only one performance measure if, and only if, the performance measure is perfectly congruent and noiseless. In other cases, more than one performance measure is recommended. Gibbs et al. (2007) find that firms use incentive systems of multiple performance measures as a response to flaws in available performance measures. Thus, bonus plans that tend to use more than just one performance measure is considered to be of higher quality.

Second, the literature on financial statement analysis (see, e.g. Bernstein and Wild, 1998; Penman, 2007) suggests that $1 of earnings is valued differently by shareholders. Earnings generated from the core business (permanent earnings) are regarded as more valuable than earnings based on transitory items (i.e. the impact of changes in accounting policies and unusual accounting items recognized as part of core earnings). Thus, bonus plans that explicitly address the consequences of unusual items and changes in accounting policies on earnings are considered to be of higher quality than other contracts.

Third, Murphy (2000) finds support for the use of external standards. He finds that income smoothing is prevalent in companies using internal standards (e.g. budgets and last year’s result), but not in companies using external standards. This suggests that bonus plans based on external standards better capture the value contribution of executives. They are, therefore, considered to be of higher quality than bonus plans that rely on internal performance standards.

Finally, Holmstrom and Milgrom (1987) suggest that the pay-to-performance structure should be linear as it mitigates the incentive to manage the performance measure. Nonlinear bonus plans provide the executives with an incentive to manage earnings. For example, if the year-to-date performance indicates that annual performance will exceed that required to achieve the bonus cap, executives will either withhold effort or ‘move’ current earnings to future periods (Healy, 1985). Thus, linear bonus plans with no cap or floor are considered to be of higher quality than other bonus plans. In summary, a well-designed bonus plan is expected to capture the actual value creation better than a poorly designed bonus plan and should, consequently, improve the pay-to-performance relation.

Hypothesis 4: The positive pay-to-performance relation is stronger for better designed bonus plans.

3. Sample

According to Danish accounting legislation privately held firms need only provide limited information on executive compensation. Due to the lack of data, we made a questionnaire survey in the spring of 2007 in order to examine current practice for compensation among privately held firms. The questionnaire focuses on the technical aspects of accounting-based bonus plans. To increase the likelihood that all relevant questions were included and that the questions were easily understood, six persons, four advisors and two executives, pretested the questionnaire. In addition, the questionnaire was tested by our colleagues. As a result of this pilot project, we made some rephrasing, added a few extra options for answering selected questions and expanded the questionnaire with further relevant questions.

The study is based on firms belonging to accounting class C (mid-size and large firms). These firms are more representative of the Danish business community than publicly traded firms. It is also considered more likely that firms in class C would fill in the questionnaire than firms in classes A and B (small firms), respectively. Organizations, firms from the public sector and funds are not included in the sample, as the incentive structure for those firms is different from other privately held firms.

Based on the above criteria, 2127 firms were selected from the database Soliditet. Five hundred of those were chosen randomly. Each of the 500 firms was contacted by phone in order to obtain e-mail addresses for every executive. If the executive board consisted of more than one member (CEO) all executives received the questionnaire. The outcome was 574 possible respondents. On 27 April 2007, the questionnaire was mailed to the respondents via an e-mail service made available by Defgo. On 21 May, 219 had opened the questionnaire and of those 191 respondents filled it in. This corresponds to a response rate of 33 per cent, which is satisfactory for questionnaires (Petersen and Plenborg, 2007). Unfortunately, not all executives filled in the questionnaire entirely, reducing sample size further. Thus, our tests are based on a sample of 125 observations. The accounting data used in our study is retrieved from Soliditet.

To clarify whether firms, which filled in the questionnaire, have specific characteristics (selection bias), we compared the respondent firms with the ones that did not reply. Data needed to do so were obtained from Soliditet; Firms that did not respond to the questionnaire had an average turnover of DKK 899 million versus DKK 863 million for firms that accepted to participate. Average total assets was DKK 617 million for firms that did not participate versus DKK 584 million for firms that filled in the questionnaire. This indicates that there is not a large difference between firms that participate and those that chose not to.

4. Research design

Agency theory posits simultaneous relations between performance and the level of pay (Anderson et al., 2000, 534). Anderson et al. (2000) find that when these simultaneous relations are ignored, the results are quite different from a simple one-stage least squares regression. In order to take into account the simultaneity of performance and pay, we run specifications using both a two-stage least squares approach and a three-stage least squares approach.

The specifications adopted to analyse the determinants of executive compensation in privately held firms are listed below:
image(1)
image(2)

We have used industry and growth as additional instrumental variables along with size and leverage. Following the advice of Stock et al. (2002), we examine whether weak instruments potentially are a problem in a given application by checking the first-stage F-statistic. In the specifications that we report first-stage F-statistic is approximately 12 in most specifications, which is above the recommended minimum level indicating strong instrumental variables.

4.1. Endogenous variables

ln(executive compensation) is defined as the natural logarithm of total salary plus bonus. Our survey data reveal that 35 executives are awarded stock options too. Due to data limitations, we are not able to estimate the value of the awarded stock options. Thus, we cannot include them as part of compensation. Previous studies examining data from privately held firms ignore the impact of stock options (see, for example, Ke et al., 1999; Cole and Mehran, 2008). We are able to distinguish executives who receive stock options in addition to bonus from executives who receive salary and bonus only. This allows us to run different types of robustness checks. First, we run a regression (equation (1)) excluding executives who receive stock options. Second, we include stock options as an explanatory variable in model (1). If the coefficient of stock options is not statistically different from zero, it indicates that stock options are equally distributed across respondents (and only the intercept will be affected by the omission of stock options).

We use three proxies for firm performance. Return on assets, defined as EBIT divided by total assets, return on equity, defined as net earnings divided by shareholders equity and net earnings.

4.2. Exogenous variables

On the basis of our hypotheses, we include board-, ownership-, executive- and quality-specific variables as explanatory variables. Included as board variables are board size, defined as the number of board members, percentage of inside board members and a dummy variable that equals 1 if the executive also serves on the board and 0 otherwise. Ownership concentration is defined as the percentage of shares owned by the largest shareholder. As executive-specific variables, we include tenure defined as the number of years that the executive has held the current position, size, measured as the natural logarithm of total assets, a dummy variable that equals 1 if the executive is CEO and 0 otherwise, a dummy variable that equals 1 if the executive holds stocks in his firm and 0 otherwise, and executive education as measured by dummy variables indicating the executive’s highest educational attainment (from primary and lower secondary school to a graduate degree).

Our quality measure of bonus plans consists of four indicators. Each indicator receives a value between 0 and 1, where 1 indicates the highest quality. The first quality indicator is the number of performance measures applied in each bonus plan. Bonus plans applying one or two performance measures obtain a score of 0.33 and 0.67, respectively. Bonus plans that apply three or more performance measures receive a score of 1. The second quality indicator is based on the level of noise in each performance measure. The information from the questionnaire allows us to rank each bonus plan based on the degree to which it considers the impact of transitory items and changes in accounting policies on the performance measures adopted. For example, if the bonus plan takes into account both transitory items and changes in accounting policies, the bonus plan receives a score of 1. The third indicator considers the quality of the performance standard. Bonus plans relying on an internal (external) standard receive a score of 0.33 (1.0). Bonus plans that rely on both an internal and external standard receive a score of 0.66. The final indicator is based on the pay-to-performance structure in each compensation contract. The questionnaire allows us to divide the bonus plans into 20 incentive zones depending on the cap and floor used. An incentive zone with no cap or floor receives a score of 1. A bonus plan with no incentive zone receives a score of 0. A factor analysis suggests that the four indicators load on the same maximum likelihood factor. Thus, we also create a quality index based on the average score of the four indicators. Each bonus plan is ranked from 0 to 1 based on the average score.

To rule out alternative explanations to our findings, we include leverage and regulated industry as control variables. Lippert and More (1994) and Lippert and Porter (1997) find that executive compensation is higher for firms with higher risk (measured as stock volatility). As stock prices are not observable for privately held firms, we adopt the level of debt-to-assets ratio as a proxy for risk. Murphy (1999) finds that the level of compensation is lower for regulated industries such as utilities. Thus, we include a dummy variable that equals 1 for regulated industries and 0 otherwise. Finally, εi is a normally distributed error term.

4.3. Alternative specification

As shown in Lambert and Larcker (1987) and Boschen et al. (2003), the relation between compensation and performance is complicated. They, therefore, suggest employing a first-difference model in line with specification (3):
image(3)
where C is compensation, X is an accounting performance measure, E is the expectation operator and ScaleQuality is a quality index that ranks each bonus plan based on four quality indicators.
Although the (first-difference) model does not explicitly estimate the long-run response of compensation to unexpected performance, the structure of the model implies that increases in compensation from unexpected performance remain permanently in the level of compensation. In order to relax this constraint we also run specification (4):
image(4)

This specification allows Ct − 1 to be positive, but less than one. In equation (3) we assume that accounting performance follows a random walk. Watts and Leftwich (1977) find that the random walk model is a good description of the process generating earnings in general, and for individual firms.

5. Descriptive statistics

The descriptive statistics are reported in Table 1. The average salary including bonus is DKK 1.9 million. Firms included in the sample generate an average return on assets of 7.8 per cent. The average (median) return on equity equals 23.4 per cent (15.1 per cent) which reflects that leverage affects shareholders’ return positively.

Table 1.
Descriptive statistics
Variable n Mean Min 25% 50% 75% Max
ln LEVELPAY 125 14.32 12.54 13.93 14.29 14.62 15.47
LEVELPAY(DKK) 125 1,860,210 280,000 1,125,000 1,608,750 2,242,500 5,250,000
Performance
 ROAt 125 0.0782 (0.4307) 0.0054 0.0805 0.1503 0.6281
 ROAt−1 125 0.1007 (0.5969) 0.0198 0.0646 0.1320 1.1343
 ROEt 125 0.2344 (15.0676) 0.0420 0.1910 0.3441 40.1682
 ROEt−1 125 0.1477 (1.7831) 0.0205 0.1630 0.3074 2.2478
 EARNINGSt (’000 DKK) 125 58,780 (680,200) 1242 15,515 40,430 2,412,000
 EARNINGSt−1 (’000 DKK) 125 49,398 (388,000) 1290 11,617 37,692 1,803,000
Corporate governance
 Executive member of board 125 0.3440 0 0 0 1 1
 Number of board members 125 5.96 3 5 6 7 10
 Relative number of insiders 125 0.66 0.11 0.40 0.60 1.00 1.00
 Ownership concentration 125 0.71 0.00 0.42 1.00 1.00 1.00
Executive characteristics
 ln Assets 125 12.50 10.09 11.72 12.40 13.37 16.98
 CEO DUMMY 125 0.69 0 0 1 1 1
 Executive ownership 125 0.3600 0 0 0 1 1
 Option dummy 125 0.2240 0 0 0 0 1
 Tenure 125 5.26 0 2 5 8 31
 Age 121 49.26 33 44 49 54 65
 Educational attainment 125 5.88 2 5 7 7 7
Quality
 SCALECAP 53 0.42 0.00 0.15 0.25 1.00 1.00
 SCALESTANDARD 53 0.37 0.33 0.33 0.33 0.33 1.00
 SCALEACCOUNTING 53 0.28 0.00 0.00 0.33 0.50 0.67
 SCALENRPERF 53 0.72 0.33 0.33 1.00 1.00 1.00
 SCALEQUALITY 53 0.45 0.19 0.38 0.44 0.54 0.75
Control
 Leverage 125 0.6871 0.1072 0.5427 0.7059 0.8228 1.4560
  • DKK is Danish Kroner. ln(LEVELPAY) is defined as the natural logarithm of the sum of total salary and bonus for the fiscal year. ROAt(t−1) is the return on assets (lag return on assets) defined as EBIT divided by beginning of the fiscal year total assets. ROEt(t−1) is the return on equity (lag return on equity) defined as net earnings divided by beginning of the fiscal year book value of equity. EARNINGSt(t−1) is the net results (lag net result) in thousands for the fiscal year. Executive member of board is an indicator variable that equals 1 if the executive holds a position on the supervisory board and zero otherwise. Number of board members is defined as the number of members of the supervisory board. Relative number of insiders is defined as the percentage of board members who are insiders. Ownership concentration is the percentage of shares owned by the largest shareholder. ln Assets is the natural logarithm of beginning of fiscal year total assets. CEO DUMMY is an indicator variable that equals one if executive hold the position as CEO and zero otherwise. Executive ownership is an indicator variable that equals one if the executive owns shares in the company and zero otherwise. Option is an indicator variable that equals one if the executive holds options in the company and zero otherwise. Tenure is defined as the number of years the executive has hold the current position in the firm. Age is the age of the executive. Educational attainment is an indicator variable running from 1 to 7 where 1 indicates primary and lower secondary school and 7 indicates a graduate degree. SCALECAP is a variable that (from 0 to 1) indicates the span over which the incentive zone is in the compensation contract. SCALESTANDARD indicates the use of internal, combination or external standards, where external standards receive the highest score. SCALEACCOUNTING indicates whether the performance measures in compensation contracts is adjusted for changes in accounting policies or transitory items. 1 indicates the highest level. SCALENRPERF indicates how many performance measures are included in the compensation contract (3 or more is coded identically). SCALEQUALITY is a quality index that ranks each bonus plan based on four quality indicators. Each bonus plan is ranked from 0 to 1 based on the average score of the four quality indicators. Leverage is defined as total debt divided by total assets.

The descriptive statistics on the corporate governance variables show that 34 per cent of the executives also hold a position on the supervisory board. Core et al. (1999) find that 76 per cent of the CEOs also serve as chairman of the board. Thus, in a one-tier system like the USA it is common for the executive to serve on the board. In a two-tier system like the Danish CEOs are not allowed to serve as chairman of the board. The average size of the supervisory board is 6.0. This is generally lower than found in publicly traded firms. Core et al. (1999) find that the average board size of publicly traded US firms is 13. Randhøy and Nielsen (2002) find that the average board size for publicly traded Norwegian and Swedish firms is 7.2. Further, on average, 66 per cent of the board members are classified as insiders. This indicates that privately held firms more frequently rely on insiders than publicly traded firms. For example, Core et al. find that only 32 per cent of the board members in their sample are classified as insiders. The average ownership concentration is 71 per cent which is considerably higher than found in studies applying publicly traded firms. This confirms that privately held firms have a higher level of ownership concentration than publicly traded firms.

The descriptive statistics on the executive characteristics reveal that the average tenure is 5.3 years. The average age of the executive is 49.3 years. Cole and Mehran (2008) find that the average age of executives in privately held US firms is almost 50 years. Approximately 70 per cent of the executives in our sample hold the position of CEO. On average, 36 per cent of the executives own stocks in their firm and more than half of the executives hold a graduate degree. Cole and Mehran (2008) find that the executives included in their sample have a lower degree of education than executives in our sample. Further, most of the US executives own stocks in their firm. The differences between the executive characteristics found in Cole and Mehran (2008) and in our sample are most likely due to differences in firm size. For example, the average turnover for the privately held US firms in Cole and Mehran (2008) is $2.1m. In our sample, the average turnover is $169m (not reported).

Finally, the descriptive statistics on the quality of the bonus plans reveal that many bonus plans do not consider the impact of transitory items and changes in accounting policies on performance measures. On the other hand, more than half of the bonus plans include three or more performance measures. Descriptive statistics on the quality index based on the average score of the four indicators show that no bonus plan meets the criteria for ‘best practice’, i.e. obtaining a score of 1 (the highest score is 0.75). Further, the quality index score does not seem to be clustered around a certain value but is normally distributed around 0.44. This increases the likelihood that the quality index may explain differences in the pay-to-performance relation across executives.

The correlations reported in Table 2 provide preliminary evidence on some of the hypotheses. First, performance, as expressed by ROA, does not seem to explain the variation in executive compensation. The correlation coefficients on ROAt and ROAt−1 are close to zero and insignificant. Second, the number of board members seems to be positively correlated with level of compensation. The correlation coefficient is significant at the 1 per cent level. The correlation coefficients on the other corporate governance characteristics remain close to zero and insignificant. Third, size is, in line with previous studies, highly correlated with level of compensation and significant at the 1 per cent level. The executive’s educational attainment also seems to explain the level of compensation. The coefficient is positive and significant at the 5 per cent level. Further, CEOs seem to receive a higher level of compensation than other executives. Other executive characteristics such as tenure and executives that own stocks in their firm do not seem to explain the variation in executive compensation. Finally, the correlation coefficient between the quality index and executive compensation is close to zero and insignificant. Some of the independent variables correlated at conventional significance levels which may indicate the presence of multicollinearity. Thus, as part of the robustness check we examine whether the reported results are affected by the presence of multicollinearity.

Table 2.
Pearson correlations between compensation and determinants
ROAt ROAt−1 Executive member of board Number of board members Relative number of insiders Ownership concentration ln  Assets CEO DUMMY Executive ownership dummy Tenure Age Educational attainment Leverage SCALEQUALITY
ln LEVELPAY 0.0704 0.1141 −0.0747 0.3254 0.0516 0.1013 0.5339 0.1557 −0.0609 0.0469 0.0109 0.1869 −0.1708 −0.6361
0.4355 0.2053 0.4077 0.0002 0.5680 0.2611 <0.0001 0.0829 0.5002 0.6033 0.9057 0.0369 0.0569 0.6509
ROAt 0.6578 0.0375 −0.0389 0.0104 0.0814 −0.0714 −0.0463 0.0131 0.1099 −0.2965 −0.0031 −0.3035 0.1490
<0.0001 0.6778 0.1613 0.9088 0.3669 0.4288 0.6080 0.8848 0.2225 0.0010 0.9723 0.0006 0.2868
ROAt−1 0.1067 −0.0912 0.0419 0.1355 −0.0552 0.0252 0.1091 0.0746 −0.0322 0.0250 −0.4120 0.0844
0.2364 0.3116 0.6431 0.1319 0.5413 0.7804 0.2258 0.4084 0.7256 0.7816 <0.0001 0.5481
Corporate governance
 Executive member of board −0.2823 0.2587 0.0468 −0.3473 0.3059 0.2989 0.0783 −0.7995 −0.1631 0.0471 −0.1211
0.0014 0.0036 0.6040 <0.0001 0.0005 0.0007 0.3852 0.3834 0.0691 0.6018 0.3876
 Number of board members −0.2653 −0.1700 0.4269 −0.0976 −0.1320 −0.0471 0.0998 0.2174 −0.0425 −0.0698
0.0028 0.0581 <0.0001 0.2789 0.1422 0.6016 0.2760 0.0149 0.6381 0.6193
 Relative number of insiders 0.0653 −0.0402 0.1901 −0.1597 0.0053 −0.1709 0.0310 0.1285 0.2809
0.4694 0.6565 0.0337 0.0753 0.9532 0.0609 0.7313 0.1532 0.0416
 Ownership concentration 0.0098 −0.1229 −0.1983 −0.1846 −0.0505 −0.0744 −0.0354 0.1612
0.9136 0.1723 0.0267 0.0393 0.5825 0.4098 0.6950 0.2489
Executive characteristics
 ln (Assets) −0.2125 −0.1523 0.1306 0.1010 0.1464 −0.1307 0.1529
0.0174 0.0900 0.1466 0.2701 0.1032 0.1464 0.2745
 CEO DUMMY 0.0734 0.0288 0.0756 −0.1291 −0.0272 −0.1199
0.4160 0.7496 0.4099 0.1514 0.7630 0.3925
 Executive ownership dummy 0.0237 0.1082 −0.0070 −0.6426 −0.1569
0.7934 0.2373 0.9383 0.4765 0.2619
 Tenure −0.4713 0.0209 −0.1332 0.0029
0.6077 0.8174 0.1388 0.9837
 Age 0.0189 0.0882 0.1099
0.8370 0.3363 0.4381
 Educational attainment 0.0025 0.1121
0.9783 0.4241
Control
 Leverage −0.1070
0.4456
  • See Table 1 for description of variables. n = 125 except for the variables Age and SCALEQUALITY where n is 121 and 53, respectively. The first number is the Pearson correlation coefficient, second number is the p-value under the null hypothesis of zero correlation.

6. Empirical results

The results of our tests of the different hypotheses are reported in Table 3. Tosi et al. (2000) conclude that firm size accounts for more than 40 per cent of the variance in executive pay. Thus, even though we define size as a proxy for executive skills, we include the variable in all our tests. In Table 3, panel A executive compensation is regressed on ROAt. The coefficient is positive as expected but not significantly different from zero. In line with our hypothesis we find a positive but weak pay-to-performance relation. The coefficient on size is positive and significant at the 1 per cent level, which confirms that size explains a significant part of the variations in executive compensation. A coefficient of 0.19 implies that every time firm size doubles compensation increases by 14 per cent. The coefficient on leverage is negative but not significantly different from zero. This result contradicts the finding of Lippert and Porter (1997), who find that executive compensation is higher for firms with higher risk. One explanation may be that firms with high financial leverage have incentives to monitor the cash (out)flows more closely and thereby also the cash compensation to executives.

Table 3.
Two-stage least squares estimation of log level of pay on performance, size, corporate governance variables, executive characteristics and quality of contract
Independent variables Predicted sign PANEL
A B C D E F
Intercept 12.0204 11.9263 11.6554 11.0855 12.2428 10.7416
23.48*** 23.05*** 21.07*** 19.73*** 15.17*** 17.39***
ROAt + 0.3652 0.1701 0.4596 0.5756 −1.4182 0.8157
0.50 0.23 0.63 0.76 −1.08 1.03
ROAt−1 + 0.2740
1.28
ln Assets + 0.1910 0.1935 0.1765 0.2123 0.2400 0.2001
6.20*** 6.27*** 4.91*** 6.79*** 4.24*** 5.46***
Corporate governance
 Executive member of board + 0.1355 0.0851
1.53 0.89
 Number of board members + 0.0479 0.0370
2.24** 1.69*
 Relative number of insiders + 0.1579 0.0431
1.15 0.30
 Ownership concentration 0.1358 0.1863
1.45 1.84*
Executive characteristics
 CEO DUMMY + 0.2960 0.3003
3.50*** 3.33***
 Interaction perf × CEO DUMMY + 0.4642 0.3568
1.62 1.20
 Executive ownership dummy 0.0085 0.0342
0.11 0.39
 Tenure + −0.0068 −0.0032
−0.96 −0.43
 Educational attainment + 0.0557 0.0560
2.14** 2.04**
Quality of contract
 SCALEQUALITY + −0.9506
−1.59
 Interaction perf × SCALEQUALITY + 1.6266
1.09
Control
 Leverage + −0.1626 −0.0906 −0.1523 0.0341 −0.5383 0.0886
−0.61 −0.33 −0.57 0.013 −1.39 0.33
n 125 125 125 125 53 125
 Adjusted R2 26.35 26.62 29.44 35.01 25.71 35.32
  • Significance at *10 per cent, **5 per cent and ***1 per cent levels. See Table 1 for description of the variables.

In Table 3, panel B we examine whether executive compensation is a function of past-year performance. Even though the coefficient on ROAt−1 is positive and higher than the coefficient on ROAt it remains insignificant. However, it indicates that executive compensation to a larger degree is determined by past-year performance than current-year performance.

In Table 3, panel C we examine the association between corporate governance characteristics and executive compensation. In line with Core et al. (1999) and Randhøy and Nielsen (2002) we find that large supervisory boards are associated with excessive executive compensation. Based on the coefficient we can infer that for every additional board member compensation will increase by nearly 5 per cent. On the other hand, the coefficients on the percentage of inside board members, executive ownership and ownership concentration are all insignificant. This indicates that neither of these corporate governance characteristics explains the variation in executive compensation. The coefficients on the variables reported in Table 3, panel A remain qualitatively the same and with similar significance levels.

The coefficients on executive characteristics are reported in Table 3, panel D. The coefficient on the CEO indicator reflects that the CEOs’ level of compensation is significantly higher than other executives’ level of compensation. On average, CEOs earn 34 per cent more than other executives. Although the pay-to-performance relation is stronger for CEOs than for other executives it is not significant. While the coefficient on ROAt is 1.04 (0.58 + 0.46) for CEOs it is 0.58 for other executives. An F-test (not reported) reveals that the coefficient on ROAt for CEOs remains insignificant. Thus, despite the difference in the coefficients on ROAt across executives the performance measure does not explain the variation in executive compensation.

In line with the results of Cole and Mehran (2008) the coefficient on executives’ educational attainment is positive and significant at conventional levels. In fact, for every improvement in educational attainment (on a scale from 1 to 7) we find that executives earn 5.7 per cent more. It supports the extensive literature that examines the impact of education on earnings. For example, Green and Riddell (2001) find that each additional year of education raises earnings by approximately 8 per cent.

Contrary to Core et al. (1999) and Randhøy and Nielsen (2002) we do not find that executive compensation is a decreasing function of the executive’s ownership stake. The coefficient on executive ownership is slightly positive but insignificant. One explanation for this finding may be that performance-related pay is less common in privately held firms resulting in a fairly constant level of compensation across different executives’ ownership stakes. The coefficient on tenure also remains insignificant indicating that this variable does not explain the variation in executive compensation.

The quality of the bonus plan is the final category of explanatory variables that we examine. We conjecture that the pay-to-performance relation is stronger for better designed bonus plans. As shown in Table 3, panel E the interaction term between performance and the quality indicator is positive and insignificant. Thus, our measure of quality does not improve the pay-to-performance relation. This may be due to a quality measure that suffers from biases or that the board chose an optimal contract given the firm’s informational environment and its demand for high-quality executives. However, the results may also be influenced by the modest number of observations available in this specification. In the robustness check below we explore this finding in further details.

As a final test we include all explanatory variables in model (1). The results reported in Table 3, panel F generally support the findings listed above. The coefficients on firm size, board size, educational attainment and CEO versus other executives remain positive and significant at conventional levels. In addition, ownership concentration seems to explain variations in executive compensation as well. However, in contrast to our expectation the coefficient is positive indicating that executive compensation improves as ownership concentration increases. We elaborate further on this finding below.

7. Robustness checks

In order to further strengthen our results we conduct a range of additional tests. First, we use return on equity and net earnings as proxies for performance. In neither of these specifications do the alternative performance measures explain the level of compensation. This finding supports that performance does not explain variations in executive compensation.

We also examine whether the pay-to-performance relation is nonlinear. One may argue that the pay-to-performance relation is only positive for firms reporting positive ROA. The basic idea is that executives still receive a salary even when ROA is negative. To examine whether this holds true we create an indicator variable that equals one when ROA is positive and zero otherwise. We multiply the indicator variable with the performance to explore whether the pay-to-performance relation is nonlinear. However, the coefficient on the interaction term remains insignificant indicating that the pay-to-performance relation is similar for firms generating both positive and negative ROAs.

In addition, we use ln(sales) and ln(employees) as proxies for size. The coefficients on both proxies remain positive and significant at the 1 per cent level. Further, the coefficients and significance levels of the other variables remain qualitatively unchanged.

We examine alternative specifications of the ownership concentration variable. First, we define ownership concentration as the sum of the three largest shareholders. The coefficient on this alternative ownership specification is positive and significant at the 5 per cent level. This supports that ownership concentration explains variations in executive compensation. Second, we examine whether the type of owners impact the level of executive compensation. Specifically, we make a distinction between institutional, firm/family, foundation and state ownership. Interestingly, only the coefficient on firm/family ownership is positive and significant. This indicates that the result found in Table 3(F) is primarily driven by firm/family ownership. Firm/family-owned businesses seem more generous with their compensation to executives than firms owned by institutional investors, foundations and the state.

Our quality indicator of the bonus plans did not improve the pay-to-performance relation. One explanation may be that we add four quality indicators that provide different types of information. Thus, we examine how each of the quality indicators influences the pay-to-performance relation. The results are reported in Table 4.

Table 4.
Two-stage least squares estimation of log level of pay on performance, size, corporate governance variables, executive characteristics and quality of contract
Independent variables Predicted sign PANEL
A: SCALE QUALITY B: SCALENR PERF C: SCALEACCOUNTING D: SCALESTANDARD E: SCALECAP
Intercept 11.6078
13.22***
11.0759
12.40***
11.3704
12.67***
11.7089
12.76***
12.1210
11.55***
ROAt + −0.6021
−0.54
−0.1105
−0.10
−0.703
−0.61
−0.5894
−0.52
−1.5843
−1.23
ln Assets + 0.1939
3.16***
0.2317
3.55***
0.1915
2.99***
0.1591
2.38***
0.1356
1.83***
Corporate governance
 Executive member of board + −0.019
0.01
0.0442
0.33
0.0221
0.15
−0.0048
−0.03
−0.082
−0.48
 Number of board members + 0.0717
2.06**
0.0481
1.35
0.0749
2.05**
0.0809
2.10**
0.0875
2.23**
 Relative number of insiders + 0.1572
0.74
0.3077
1.40
0.0728
0.33
0.1452
0.63
0.0442
0.19
 Ownership concentration 0.2336
1.49
0.1917
1.30
0.2031
1.27
0.1588
1.01
0.2510
1.48
Executive characteristics
 CEO DUMMY + 0.3305
2.16**
0.2845
2.03**
0.3078
2.12**
0.2287
1.42
0.4322
2.63**
 Interaction perf × CEO DUMMY + 0.8236
0.76
0.6964
0.75
1.0022
1.57
2.3374
1.78*
0.4005
0.49
 Executive ownership dummy 0.0861
0.65
0.1014
0.79
0.079
0.57
0.0618
0.45
0.0779
0.53
 Tenure + −0.0203
−1.87*
−0.0222
−2.13**
−0.0214
−1.82*
−0.0235
−2.06**
−0.0200
−1.67
 Educational attainment + 0.0529
1.36
0.0559
1.49
0.0385
0.97
0.0334
0.83
0.0508
1.19
Quality of contract
 QUALITY + −1.0359
−1.90*
−0.5206
−2.13**
−0.1481
−0.55
0.3781
0.56
−0.4314
−1.45
 Interaction perf × QUALITY + 0.8527
0.37
0.2181
0.22
0.6327
0.34
−2.7770
−1.08
2.691
1.49
Control
 Leverage + −0.4463
−1.31
−0.4385
−1.33
−0.4139
−1.14
−0.4582
−1.26
−0.5411
−1.41
n 53 53 53 53 53
 Adjusted R2 48.87 51.81 43.82 44.57 41.54
  • Significance at *10 per cent, **5 per cent and ***1 per cent levels. See Table 1 for description of the variables.

As can be seen from Table 4, the coefficients on the interaction terms take different signs. While the coefficient on performance standards is negative the coefficients on the other three quality indicators are positive. Thus, the quality indicators seem to provide different information on the pay-to-performance relation. None of the coefficients are, however, significantly different from zero.

We also used an alternative indicator for the quality of the compensation contracts. The participants in our survey rated the compensation contract based on their perception of the quality of the compensation contract. We used that rating as an indicator of the overall quality of the compensation contract and created a new interaction term (ROA × rating). We conjecture that the pay-to-performance relation will be stronger for compensation contracts receiving a high rating. The coefficient on the interaction term remains close to zero and insignificant. Thus, our different proxies for quality do not improve the pay-to-performance relation.

As mentioned above, we cannot include stock options as part of executive compensation due to data limitations. However, we repeat our test excluding executives that receive stock options as part of their compensation. The results remain similar to the results based on the full sample. Finally, we also included stock options as an explanatory (indicator) variable in model (1). The coefficient on the stock options remains close to zero and insignificant. This indicates that stock options are equally distributed across respondents. We, therefore, believe that our results are robust, even though we are not able to include the value of awarded stock options in the calculation of executives’ compensation.

As the relation between compensation and performance is complicated Lambert and Larcker (1987) and Boschen et al. (2003) suggest employing a first-difference model in line with specifications (2) and (3), respectively. In Table 5, we report the results for these specifications. In line with the results reported in Tables 3 and 4, performance does not explain the change in compensation. Size, on the other hand, remains an important determinant for executive compensation.

Table 5.
Two-stage least squares estimation of log change in pay on change in performance and size
Independent variables Predicted sign
Panel A: Estimation of log change in pay on change in performance and size
Intercept 7.8242
9.79***
DeltaROA + 0.3561
0.60
ln Assets + 0.2719
4.26***
n 87
Adjusted R2 15.99
Panel B: Estimation of log level of pay on lag log level of payt−1, change in performance and size
Intercept 0.3479
1.76*
ln(LEVELPAY)t−1 + 0.9682
61.78***
DeltaROA + −0.0235
−0.57
ln Assets + 0.0124
2.23**
n 114
Adjusted R2 97.94
  • Significance at *10 per cent, **5 per cent and ***1 per cent levels. See Table 1 for description of the variables.

As noted above some of the independent variables correlated at conventional significance levels which indicate the presence of multicollinearity. Consequently, we examine the robustness of the reported results by excluding one independent variable at a time. The results of the reduced model remain similar to the reported results based on the full model. This indicates that the reported findings are not affected by multicollinearity. In summary, the results from the different robustness checks support the statistics reported in Table 3.

8. Summary and conclusions

This paper documents how four different categories of determinants affect executive compensation in privately held firms in Denmark. In line with our predictions we find that the pay-to-performance relation is weak. Corporate governance characteristics only vaguely explain determinants of executive compensation. Board size and ownership concentration are the only corporate governance characteristics that explain variations in executive compensation. On the other hand, we find that executive characteristics like skills (size), executive position and educational level are important in explaining variations in executive compensation. Finally, as a novelty we allow the quality of the bonus plan to vary across executives. Contrary to our expectations we do not find a stronger pay-to-performance relation in firms with better designed bonus plans.

Our study confirms that research on privately held firms that are based on an institutional setting and that deviate from the UK and the USA, respectively, offers insightful results. First, the weak pay-to-performance relation is most likely explained by the fact that: (i) performance-related pay is less common in privately held firms in Denmark and (ii) earnings is a relatively more noisy measure of performance in privately held firms than in publicly traded firms (Ball and Shivakumar, 2005).

Second, we only find one board characteristic that explains variations in executive compensation. Other studies that rely on publicly traded firms find evidence of a significant association between many of the board characteristics and CEO compensation. One explanation for our finding may be that board characteristics in privately held firms simply serve as ‘noisy measures’ of the same variables that determine executive compensation. Differences in the institutional settings may serve as an alternative explanation. For example, in contrast to Core et al. (1999) we do not find that the level of executive compensation is higher in firms where the executive also serves on the board. This is most likely due to the fact that executives in Denmark are not allowed to serve as chairman of the supervisory board. Third, the executive’s educational attainment proves to be an important explanatory variable in explaining variations in executive compensation. To our knowledge only a few compensation studies have included executive characteristics like educational attainment when explaining variations in executive compensation.

Finally, the inability to explain variations in the pay-to-performance relation based on our quality index is surprising. In the literature there are strong arguments in favour of including the quality index. For example, it seems obvious that bonus plans that consider the impact of transitory items (for example, restructuring charges) and changes in accounting policies on the adopted performance measures are of better quality than bonus plans that ignore these effects. One explanation for this surprising finding may be that the underlying pay-to-performance relation is weak. Another explanation may be that the quality index is not properly specified. For example, we regard bonus plans that include three or more performance measures as better than bonus plans that rely on only one or two performance measures. It is not clear whether this distinction is appropriate. Obviously, the limited number of observations in the specifications including the quality index also reduces the chances of a significant coefficient on the quality index.

We believe that our study can be expanded in different ways. Future studies may examine whether the weak pay-to-performance relation identified in privately held firms is a result of an efficient corporate governance structure or a result of poorly designed compensation contract. Second, although the coefficient on our quality index remains insignificant we believe that a way to expand the study is to explore each compensation contract in further detail. Previous studies assume that the quality of the executive compensation contract is identical. Future studies may shed light on why some compensation contracts contain only one performance measure while other contracts include three or more performance measures. Further, why do some contracts ignore the impact of transitory items on performance measures adopted while other contracts carefully consider these items? And why is the pay-to-performance relation not stronger for firms that carefully consider the impact of transitory items? These issues ought to be further examined. Finally, it seems worthwhile to replicate our study in a setting where the pay-to-performance relation has proved to be strong.

Footnotes

  • 1 It is important to stress that the Nordic countries including Denmark, Finland, Norway and Sweden are similar in terms of GDP, growth in GDP and inhabitants. Iceland is significantly smaller based on these criteria.
  • 2 Lambert et al. (1993) and Boyd (1994) obtain similar results.
  • 3 A copy of the questionnaire may be obtained by request to the authors.
  • 4 Soliditet is a database containing information on firm-specific data such as management board members, members of the supervisory board and corporate structure. Furthermore, the database contains information from financial reports and ratios based on accounting information. Soliditet is part of Dun & Bradstreet.
  • 5 This took place in a random procedure in Microsoft Excel.
  • 6 In cases where we have more than 125 observations available we repeat the test. These tests produce results similar to the ones reported in this study (not reported).
  • 7 As both approaches yield similar results, we only report results based on a two-stage least squares approach.
  • 8 Even though we apply a two-stage least squares approach, we only report the results where executive compensation serves as the response variable.
  • 9 We have examined the impact of other explanatory variables such as ownership concentration and managerial ownership. However, the results remain similar to the simple performance equation (2).
  • 10 Alternative definitions of ownership concentration are also applied.
  • 11 There are only four regulated (telecom, utilities, financial institutions and transportation) companies included in the sample and they do not affect the results reported. We therefore report the results without including the industry dummy.
  • 12 It is important to stress that by using a first-difference model we do not need to control for the same factors as in a level specification. Thus, in addition to the quality index (interaction term), we only control for size which is in line with Boschen et al. (2003).
  • 13 In the alternative specification where ROA serves as the response variable, the coefficient on executive compensation remains close to zero and insignificant. This indicates that the performance-to-pay relation is also weak.
  • 14 Please note, that only firms with bonus plans are included in the test. This more than halved the sample size.
  • 15 Due to data restrictions, we exclude the quality measure of bonus plans from our test.
  • 16 The way that ownership data are reported in Denmark makes it difficult to make a distinction between family and firm ownership, respectively. Thus, we combine the two types of ownership into one ownership variable.
  • 17 Due to missing observations we exclude the quality index.
    • The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.