Fundamental and technical analysis: substitutes or complements?
We gratefully acknowledge the comments and suggestions offered by F. Douglas Foster, Tom Smith, Garry Twite, Baljit Sidhu, participants at the 2006 Journal of Banking and Finance Conference, the editor of Accounting and Finance, Robert Faff, and an anonymous referee. All errors are our own.
Abstract
Although the fundamental and technical analysis literatures invest considerable effort in assessing their respective ability to explain share prices, they invariably do so without reference to each other. In this context, we propose an equity valuation model integrating both fundamental and technical analysis and, in doing so, recognize their potential as complements rather than as substitutes. Testing confirms the complementary nature of fundamental and technical analysis by showing that, although each performs well in isolation, models integrating both have superior explanatory power. While our findings relate to the valuation of shares, they also have implications for other valuation exercises.
1. Introduction and literature review
Identifying the factors important in explaining contemporaneous equity prices has long been a focus of the valuation literature, with research divisible into the two rich but largely distinct and often competing arms of fundamental and technical analysis. Although proponents of each type of analysis have invariably agreed upon the general nature of factors important in explaining share prices, identifying specific value-relevant variables is a point of ongoing debate.
Graham and Dodd (1934) are among the first to formally argue the importance of fundamental factors in share valuation exercises. Subsequent studies further detail the relationship between share price and fundamental factors, with Gordon and Shapiro's (1956) Dividend Discount Model not only becoming one of the most widely cited models in modern finance theory, but also providing the foundation for voluminous subsequent research. In the context of the present study, the most notable extension of Gordon and Shapiro's (1956) work is provided by Ohlson (1995), who formulates a model expressing price as a linear function of book value per share, earnings per share and a vector of other value-relevant information. Subsequent research invests considerable effort in empirically testing numerous variations of Ohlson's (1995) Residual Income Valuation Model, with early studies invariably lending support to the (positive) dependence of equity values on both book value per share and earnings per share (see e.g. Collins et al., 1997). More recently, researchers have turned their focus to identifying variables forming part of Ohlson's (1995) vector of other value-relevant information. Specifically, Dechow et al. (1999) augment a two-factor model similar to that tested by Collins et al. (1997) with a forecasted consensus earnings measure. Fitting the resultant three-factor model reveals that, although forecast earnings is significant and positive in explaining price, its inclusion sees contemporaneous earnings ceasing to be value relevant. Dechow et al. (1999, p. 26) suggest that this result is not unexpected as ‘analysts’ forecasts of next year's earnings subsume value relevant information in current earnings’. In addition to exploring the importance of book values and current and forecast earnings in explaining price, the literature also considers the value relevance of a suite of other accounting variables (see e.g. Amir and Lev, 1996; Amir et al., 1997), with a comprehensive summary of these findings provided by Holthausen and Watts (2001). Although recent empirical research diverges in its search for other value-relevant variables, there seems little disagreement regarding the appropriateness of Ohlson's (1995) model as a foundation for these fundamental valuation exercises.
As with fundamental analysis, the ability of technical analysis to explain share prices has long fascinated practitioners and academics. Indeed, recognition of the potential for past prices, and movements therein, to predict future equity values dates back to a series of editorials published by Charles Dow in the Wall Street Journal between 1900 and 1902. The publication of these editorials prompted further research into the ability of technical analysis to explain current and future share prices as well as equity returns. One arm of this literature dismisses the random walk hypothesis, unanimously agreeing upon the ability of past prices to forecast future returns (see e.g. Lo and MacKinlay, 1988, 1999).
Another arm of technical research tests the ability of various trading rules to generate superior profits, with these studies providing support for the role of technical analysis in predicting future share performance (see e.g. Brock et al., 1992; Allen and Karjalianen, 1999). However, the reliability of these results are called into question by research as early as that of Jensen and Bennington (1970), who argue their potential to be explained by data-snooping biases. Despite the ongoing presence of such criticisms, a technique that comprehensively accounts for data-snooping biases is not incorporated in testing prior to Sullivan et al. (1999), who apply White's Reality Check bootstrap methodology to the trading rules and dataset of Brock et al. (1992). Interestingly, the application of this technique sees that findings remain unchanged. However, when re-performing testing out of sample, Sullivan et al. (1999) report that all profits associated with the trading rules of Brock et al. (1992) disappear. In light of the sensitivity of results to the use of a more recent dataset, Sullivan et al. (1999, p. 1684) conclude that, although data-snooping biases might not explain the historical profitability of trading based on technical analysis, such trading practices are no longer viable given the increased efficiency of equity markets afforded by ‘cheaper computing power, the lower transaction costs and increased liquidity’. This argument is supported by Ready (2002), who documents the inability of the trading rules of either Brock et al. (1992) or Allen and Karjalianen (1999) to consistently outperform a buy and hold strategy in recent times.
Yet another subset of the technical literature is that considering the profitability of momentum strategies, which involve the formation of portfolios based on historical performance and holding them for a predefined period. While momentum research supports the profitability of buying a portfolio of past ‘winners’ and simultaneously short selling a portfolio of past ‘losers’, then holding the resultant position for 3–12 months (see e.g. Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993, 2001), it has met with considerable scepticism given the challenge it poses for the Efficient Market Hypothesis. However, proponents of momentum subsequently provide evidence dismissive of these concerns, which include data snooping and questions regarding the economic significance of results. Moreover, robustness testing reveals that profits are robust to the introduction of transaction costs (see e.g. Korajczyk and Sadka, 2004) as well as through time (see e.g. Grundy and Martin, 2001; Jegadeesh and Titman, 2001) and across multiple equity markets (see e.g. Rouwenhorst, 1998; Liu et al., 1999; Griffin et al., 2003).
Taking the preceding discussion as a whole, two types of technical analysis are consistently documented as important in predicting prices and returns: lagged price and momentum. Indeed, their importance has already been recognized outside the technical analysis literature. By way of example, the ability of momentum to explain the cross-sectional variation in returns has already been recognized by Carhart (1997), who reports its significance in explaining mutual fund performance persistence when supplementing Fama and French's (1993) three factors to form a four-factor asset pricing model. Furthermore, the complementary nature of technical and fundamental analysis is identified by Taylor and Allen (1992). They note that some 90 per cent of foreign exchange market dealers rely on both technical and fundamental analysis.
Notwithstanding the preceding discussion, models simultaneously incorporating both fundamental and technical explanators of equity prices are all but non-existent. In this context, we propose valuation models that integrate aspects of both fundamental and technical analysis and, in doing so, recognize their potential as complements rather than substitutes. The ideal framework with which to do this is afforded by an unconstrained version of Ohlson's (1995) valuation model, a model that we augment with lagged price and two momentum dummy variables. However, to allow for the possibility that fundamental and technical analyses are not complementary, we commence by modelling price solely as a function of fundamental factors and, thereafter, consider the ability of technical factors in isolation to explain price. Next, we fit our hybrid models and, lastly, consider the performance of these models relative to those modelling price solely as a function of either fundamental or technical factors.
The results of testing our hybrid model not only reveal the importance of both fundamental and technical analyses in explaining price, but also confirm the superior explanatory power of the model relative to those considering either fundamental or technical variables in isolation. This strength of our hybrid models is best evidenced by their markedly higher (lower) adjusted R2 (Akaike Information Criterion (AIC)) values relative to models solely incorporating either fundamental or technical measures, with further verification provided by the highly significant likelihood-ratio tests.
The remainder of the present paper is structured as follows: Section 2 outlines the methodology used in assessing the ability of fundamental and technical analysis to explain share prices both in isolation and in combination; Section 3 describes the characteristics of the dataset used in testing in the current paper, also discussing the process used in collecting it; Section 4 presents and discusses key results of testing; and Section 5 concludes.
2. Model design
Before providing evidence on the complementary nature of fundamental and technical analysis in equity valuation exercises, we examine their ability to explain share prices in isolation. Moreover, we first fit a two-factor fundamental model similar to that of Collins et al. (1997), relating price to the book value per share and current earnings per share. This model is formally presented as follows, with all variables as defined in Table 1:
Variable | Definition | Data source |
---|---|---|
Pt +1 | The firm's end-of-month share price in the month forecast earnings for the coming fiscal year are announced. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes using the cumulative adjustment factor. | CRSP |
Pt –5 | The firm's end-of-month share price 6 months prior to that denoted by Pt+1. This share price is the price at the end of the formation period for momentum dummies, and is adjusted for capitalization changes using the cumulative adjustment factor. | CRSP |
BVPSt | The book value of the firm's equity (data60) scaled by shares outstanding (data25) and subsequently adjusted for capitalization changes (data27). This ratio is calculated as at the end of the most recent fiscal year relative to month t. | Compustat Industrial Annual |
EPSt | The diluted earnings per share of the firm (data57) adjusted for capitalization changes (data27). This ratio is calculated at the end of the most recent fiscal year relative to month t and announced to the market in month t. | Compustat Industrial Annual |
FEPSt +1 | The consensus forecast earnings per share for the firm, as forecast in the month following the release of actual earnings per share figures for the most recent fiscal year. Forecast earnings are adjusted for capitalization changes and are announced in the middle of the month, although the exact date varies slightly. | I/B/E/S |
DUp | A dummy variable equal to 1 if the stock holding period return in the 6 month period commencing 1 year prior to the measurement of Pt+1 placed it in the highest performance decile, and 0 otherwise. | CRSP |
DDown | A dummy variable equal to 1 if the stock holding period return in the 6 month period commencing 1 year prior to the measurement of Pt+1 placed it in the lowest performance decile, and 0 otherwise. | CRSP |
- Table 1 includes the definitions of all variables used in Models (1) to (5). More specifically, the table details the manner in which variations are calculated, as well as providing information on the source of variable constituents. CRSP, Center for Research and Security Prices; I/B/E/S, Institutional Brokers Estimate System
Pt +1 = α + β1BVPSt + β2EPSt.
()Previous testing of models similar to (1) reveals that price is highly positively dependent on book value per share (see e.g. Collins et al., 1997; Dechow et al., 1999; Ely and Waymire, 1999). Two reasons have been advanced for this dependence. The first relates to the clean surplus valuation framework used by Ohlson (1995), where book value per share anchors valuation exercises by representing the resources a firm has, which can be devoted to generated earnings in the future. The second argument suggests that book value per share will be a positive explanator of price as it represents the liquidation or adaptation value of the firm's assets (see Berger et al., 1996; Burgstahler and Dichev, 1997, respectively). As with book value per share, research confirms current earnings per share as a positive explanator of share price (see e.g. Easton, 1985; Collins et al., 1997; Dechow et al., 1999; Ely and Waymire, 1999). The main explanation offered for this finding is that contemporaneous earnings per share serves as a proxy for the current value of the firm, or its value in use, as opposed to book value per share, which represents its exit value (see e.g. Barth et al., 1996).
Subsequent research supplements a model similar to (1) with forecast earnings per share (see e.g. Dechow et al., 1999), arguing that it represents a proxy for the other value-relevant information variable included in Ohlson's (1995) model. We test an unconstrained version of the resultant model, expressed below, with variables as defined in Table 1:
Pt +1 = α + β1BVPSt + β2EPSt + β3FEPSt+1.
()Similar testing undertaken in earlier research reveals an interesting result: Although price exhibits the expected positive statistical dependence on both book value per share and the consensus forecast earnings per share, current earnings per share ceases to be a significant explanator given the presence of the aforementioned independent variables. Dechow et al. (1999) argue that such a result is consistent with the consensus forecast earnings measure not only subsuming the information contained in the current earnings figure, but also offering incremental information about the future prospects of the company.
Next, in providing evidence on the ability of technical analysis to explain equity values, we model price as a function of past price and our momentum measures. Our model is formally presented below, with variables as defined in Table 1:
Pt +1 = α + β1Pt–5 + β2DUp + β3DDown.
()Model (3) incorporates lagged price as an explanator given that the technical literature unanimously agrees on its ability to forecast future returns (see e.g. Lo and MacKinlay, 1988, 1999). Similarly, momentum factors are included in light of strong evidence suggesting performance persistence in equity markets (see e.g. Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993) and the robustness of these findings to critiques of data-snooping biases (see e.g. Grundy and Martin, 2001; Jegadeesh and Titman, 2001) and economic insignificance (see e.g. Korajczyk and Sadka, 2004).
The momentum factors incorporated in Model (3) are dummy variables capturing extreme past return performance and are assigned based on the momentum measure advanced by Jegadeesh and Titman (1993, 2001). In constructing these variables, we first calculate the buy and hold return on shares accruing over the 6 month period commencing exactly 1 year from the time we model price, an approach analogous to calculating Jegadeesh and Titman's (1993, 2001) formation period return. Based on these returns, we rank shares and assign them to performance deciles. Shares included in the top (bottom) decile are allocated a DUp (DDown) dummy equal to 1 in order to reflect their extreme positive (negative) performance over the period. Conversely, all shares in the remaining deciles are assigned momentum dummies equal to 0. If performance does indeed persist over the ensuing 6 months, a timeframe equivalent to Jegadeesh and Titman's (1993, 2001) performance period, we expect to see DUp (DDown) as a significantly positive (negative) explanator of price when fitting Model (3).
After fitting models of price as a function of either fundamental or technical factors, we incorporate both sets of measures to generate our hybrid models. More specifically, we supplement Models (1) and (2) with the suite of technical factors included in (3), yielding Models (4) and (5). Again, variables are as defined in Table 1:
Pt +1 = α + β1BVPSt + β2EPSt + β3Pt–5 + β4DUp + β5DDown,
()Pt +1 = α + β1BVPSt + β2EPSt + β3FEPSt+5 + β4Pt–5 + β5DUp + β6DDown.
()Finally, in order to undertake a meaningful comparison of the explanatory power of Models (1) to (5) and, in doing so, draw inferences regarding the model best able to explain contemporaneous share prices, we use three goodness-of-fit criterion; namely, the adjusted R2, AIC and likelihood-ratio tests.1 Results of testing are discussed in detail in Section 4.
3. Data and variable measurement
In undertaking the testing outlined in Section 2, we use a dataset pertaining to US listed companies that spans the period January 1983 through December 2002 inclusive, with our initial sample comprising the universe of companies for which all necessary data is available. Specifically, accounting variables are sourced from the Compustat Industrial Annual files, with share prices and holding period returns obtained from the Center for Research and Security Prices files and earnings forecasts downloaded from the Institutional Brokers Estimate System (I/B/E/S). Initially, we utilize return information for the entire universe of companies to calculate the momentum dummies in the manner described in Section 2. Thereafter, accounting variables, forecast earnings data and momentum dummies are merged using unique company identifiers, with all incomplete observations excluded from modelling.
As detailed in Table 1, which includes comprehensive definitions of the calculation of variables employed in testing, both book value per share and (diluted) current earnings per share measures relate to the most recently ended fiscal year. The month in which the aforementioned accounting information is released to the market is ascertained from I/B/E/S, with the consensus forecast earnings per share measure taken in the month following the release of these figures. To ensure the comparability of the forecast figures obtained from I/B/E/S with the reported (diluted) earnings figures obtained from Compustat, before proceeding further, we convert all forecast figures reported on a primary basis into diluted equivalents. In undertaking this exercise, we exclude any observation for which the basis of reporting forecast earnings figures cannot be ascertained. Finally, with respect to the dependent price variable incorporated in modelling, as forecast earnings figures are invariably released in the middle of any given month, to ensure the market has had opportunity to impound this information, we take prices at the end of the same month. This matching approach is similar to that used by prior research including that of Dechow et al. (1999).
After merging the aforementioned datasets, we apply several filters to the resultant sample. Specifically, consistent with prior work including that of Collins et al. (1997) and Morel (2003), we remove from the sample any companies with book values per share equal to or less than 0. Furthermore, given the reporting requirements of the Security and Exchange Commission, we exclude any companies who take in excess of 90 days from the fiscal year-end to disclose annual financial information to the market.
Our final pooled cross-sectional sample comprises 33 952 firm-year observations, with descriptive statistics and correlation coefficients calculated in respect of this dataset presented in Tables 2 and 3, respectively. Examination of these tables reveals nothing of great concern with respect to multicollinearity and also confirms that the companies included in our sample are representative of the market as a whole, being drawn from the entire size gamut.
Variable | Mean | Standard deviation | Minimum | Maximum | 25th percentile | Median | 75th percentile |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Pt +1 | 16.6087 | 13.6045 | 0.0713 | 154.5000 | 7.0000 | 13.2500 | 22.2500 |
Pt –5 | 16.1741 | 13.0828 | 0.0866 | 132.0000 | 7.0000 | 12.8570 | 21.5000 |
BVPSt | 8.0939 | 7.3014 | 0.0003 | 21.3054 | 3.2309 | 6.1797 | 10.7932 |
EPSt | 0.6374 | 1.6741 | –25.5900 | 23.5440 | 0.1377 | 0.6098 | 1.2200 |
FEPSt +1 | 1.0153 | 1.1629 | –9.6300 | 35.0000 | 0.3800 | 0.8500 | 1.5000 |
- Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for the sample used in testing (n = 33 952). Notation used in this Table 1 is as follows: Pt+1 is the firm's end-of-month share price in the month forecast earnings for the coming fiscal year are announced. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; Pt–5 is the firm's end-of-month share price 6 months prior to that denoted by Pt+1. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; BVPSt is the book value per share of the firm's equity, calculated as at the end of the most recent fiscal year and adjusted for capitalization changes; EPSt is the earnings per share of the firm, calculated at the end of the most recent fiscal year, announced to the market in month t and adjusted for capitalization changes; and FEPSt+1 is the consensus forecast earnings per share for the firm, as forecasted in the month following the release of actual earnings per share figures for the most recent fiscal year. Forecast earnings are adjusted for capitalization changes and are announced in the middle of the month, although the exact date varies slightly.
Pt +1 | Pt –5 | BVPSt | EPSt | FEPSt +2 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Pt +1 | 1.0000 | ||||
Pt –5 | 0.8682 | 1.0000 | |||
BVPSt | 0.5660 | 0.5887 | 1.0000 | ||
EPSt | 0.3840 | 0.3634 | 0.3857 | 1.0000 | |
FEPSt +1 | 0.6221 | 0.6111 | 0.6644 | 0.6025 | 1.0000 |
- Table 3 presents the correlation matrices for the sample used in testing (n = 33 952). Notation used in this Table 1 is as follows: Pt+1 is the firm's end-of-month share price in the month forecast earnings for the coming fiscal year are announced. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; Pt–5 is the firm's end-of-month share price 6 months prior to that denoted by Pt+1. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; BVPSt is the book value per share of the firm's equity, calculated as at the end of the most recent fiscal year and adjusted for capitalization changes; EPSt is the earnings per share of the firm, calculated at the end of the most recent fiscal year, announced to the market in month t and adjusted for capitalization changes; and FEPSt+1 is the consensus forecast earnings per share for the firm, as forecasted in the month following the release of actual earnings per share figures for the most recent fiscal year. Forecast earnings are adjusted for capitalization changes and are announced in the middle of the month, although the exact date varies slightly.
To allay any concerns that might stem from us having used time series data in our analysis, we perform a suite of additional tests. First, to allay any non-stationarity concerns in relation to price, we perform an augmented Dickey–Fuller test, with testing confirming that that price is indeed stationary. Thereafter, we repeat testing using a cross-sectional sample pertaining to one of our sample years, and confirm our results are insensitive to this change in data. Finally, a ramification of using a pooled cross-sectional dataset is that our error terms might have a correlation structure capable of impacting on our reported results. To confirm that this is not the case, in addition to using heteroscedacity and autocorrelation consistent standard errors, consistent with Petersen (2008), we re-perform testing using generalized least squares with fixed effects, with our results remaining unchanged.
4. Empirical results
Prior to considering whether fundamental and technical analyses complement one another in the context of equity valuation exercises, we examine the explanatory power of each type of analysis in isolation. Moreover, we commence by discussing the results of fitting Models (1) and (2), which explain price solely as a function of fundamental factors. These results are formally presented in Table 4. With respect to Model (1), testing reveals that price is highly positively dependent on book value per share, a finding consistent with the clean surplus valuation framework advanced by Ohlson (1995), the liquidity and adaptation value of assets argument and the results of prior empirical testing (see e.g. Collins et al., 1997; Dechow et al., 1999; Ely and Waymire, 1999). Testing also reveals that price exhibits a highly positive statistical dependence on current earnings per share. Again, this finding is consistent with the extant literature (see e.g. Easton, 1985; Collins et al., 1997; Dechow et al., 1999; Ely and Waymire, 1999) and the argument that earnings per share serves as a proxy of the firm's value in use. Overall, the model is highly significant and has an adjusted R2 of 35.26 per cent.
(1) | (2) | |
---|---|---|
Intercept | 8.1960 | 7.2906 |
(35.2001***) | (35.2253***) | |
BVPSt | 0.9148 | 0.5106 |
(24.3267***) | (16.9394***) | |
EPSt | 1.5815 | 0.1686 |
(5.0182***) | (1.8556) | |
FEPSt +1 | 5.0011 | |
(18.0052***) | ||
Sample | 33 952 | 33 952 |
Adjusted R2 | 0.3526 | 0.4290 |
Akaike Information Criterion | 7.6239 | 7.4985 |
F-statistic | 9 247*** | 8 502*** |
Log likelihood | –129 421 | –127 291 |
- ** and *** denote significance at the 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Notation employed in this table is as follows: Pt+1 is the firm's end-of-month share price in the month forecast earnings for the coming fiscal year are announced. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; BVPSt is the book value per share of the firm's equity, calculated as at the end of the most recent fiscal year and adjusted for capitalization changes; EPSt is the earnings per share of the firm, calculated at the end of the most recent fiscal year, announced to the market in month t and adjusted for capitalization changes; and FEPSt+1 is the consensus forecast earnings per share for the firm, as forecasted in the month following the release of actual earnings per share figures for the most recent fiscal year. Forecast earnings are adjusted for capitalization changes and are announced in the middle of the month, although the exact date varies slightly.
The results of fitting Model (2) differ somewhat from those pertaining to Model (1). Specifically, although the inclusion of consensus forecast earnings per share does not alter findings with respect to book value, its introduction sees contemporaneous earnings become an insignificant explanator of share price. Instead, the forecast earnings measure itself is revealed as a significant and positive explanator of price. Although these findings are at odds with our earlier testing, they are consistent with Dechow et al. (1999), who argue that forecast earnings per share not only subsumes current earnings figures, but also offers incremental information about the ongoing value of the firm. Notwithstanding these differences, Model (2) is highly significant in explaining equity prices, with an adjusted R2 of 42.90 per cent.
Next, in considering the ability of technical analysis to explain contemporaneous price, we examine the results of fitting Model (3), which are presented in Table 5. Results show that all technical factors are highly significant in explaining contemporaneous price and are significant in the predicted directions. Not only do contemporaneous prices exhibits a positive dependence on lagged prices, shares exhibiting returns in the 6 month formation period that place them in the top (bottom) performance decile continue to enjoy similar positive (negative) performance in the subsequent 6 months. This persistence results in systematically higher (lower) prices for these particular firms at the time we model price – namely, at the conclusion of the 12 month period – and is consistent with the performance persistence documented by the momentum literature (see e.g. Jegadeesh and Titman, 1993, 2001). Moreover, the overall model is highly significant, with an adjusted R2 of 75.46 per cent. Interestingly, results suggest that technical analysis has a greater ability to explain equity values in isolation than fundamental analysis.
(3) | (4) | (5) | |
---|---|---|---|
Intercept | 2.0759 | 1.6522 | 1.6260 |
(11.9605***) | (10.7651***) | (11.7158***) | |
BVPSt | 0.1354 | 0.0509 | |
(9.2841***) | (4.0977***) | ||
EPSt | 0.5182 | 0.1594 | |
(4.5850***) | (2.8641***) | ||
FEPSt +1 | 1.4341 | ||
(9.4222***) | |||
Pt –5 | 0.8980 | 0.8307 | 0.7978 |
(73.5508***) | (50.6868***) | (45.1158***) | |
DUp | 0.8636 | 1.3863 | 1.4168 |
(3.2020***) | (5.2897***) | (5.5928***) | |
DDown | –1.3173 | –0.6790 | –0.4712 |
(–8.8491***) | (–4.1387***) | (–3.6984***) | |
Sample | 33 952 | 33 952 | 33 952 |
Adjusted R2 | 0.7546 | 0.7629 | 0.7686 |
Akaike Information Criterion | 6.6540 | 6.6195 | 6.5955 |
F-statistic | 34 800*** | 21 850*** | 18 790*** |
Log likelihood | –112 954 | –112 366 | –111 959 |
- ** and *** denotes significance at the 5 and 1 per cent levels, respectively. Notation employed in this table is as follows: Pt+1 is the firm's end-of-month share price in the month forecast earnings for the coming fiscal year are announced. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; Pt–5 is the firm's end-of-month share price 6 months prior to that denoted by Pt+1. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; DUp is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the stock performed in the top decile in the 6 month period commencing 1 year prior to the measurement of Pt+1, and 0 otherwise; DDown is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the stock performed in the lowest decile in the 6 month period commencing 1 year prior to the measurement of Pt+1, and 0 otherwise; BVPSt is the book value per share of the firm's equity, calculated as at the end of the most recent fiscal year and adjusted for capitalization changes; EPSt is the earnings per share of the firm, calculated at the end of the most recent fiscal year, announced to the market in month t and adjusted for capitalization changes; and FEPSt+1 is the consensus forecast earnings per share for the firm, as forecasted in the month following the release of actual earnings per share figures for the most recent fiscal year. Forecast earnings are adjusted for capitalization changes and are announced in the middle of the month, although the exact date varies slightly.
Although the preceding discussion provides evidence of the explanatory power of both fundamental and technical analysis in isolation, it says nothing about whether they act as complements in equity valuation exercises. We provide evidence on this by fitting Models (4) and (5), with results of this testing provided in Table 5. With respect to the former, results reveal the significance of both types of analysis in explaining share price. More specifically, consistent with the findings in relation to Model (1) and the extant literature (see e.g. Collins et al., 1997; Ely and Waymire, 1999), book value per share and earnings per share are significant positive explanators of contemporaneous share price. Furthermore, consistent with Model (3), testing reveals the importance of technical analysis even in the presence of fundamental factors, with lagged price and both momentum dummies remaining significant in explaining contemporaneous price. Additionally, Model (4) is highly significant and has an adjusted R2 of 76.29 per cent.
As with Model (4), the results of fitting Model (5) lend support to the complementary relationship between fundamental and technical analysis, confirming the significance of each type of measure even given the presence of the other. Interestingly, in the context of our hybrid model, the inclusion of the forecast earnings per share does not detract from the significance of the contemporaneous earnings measure in explaining price. This finding is at odds with that of Dechow et al. (1999), who report that forecast earnings per share subsume the information contained in the current earnings measure. Despite this point of difference, Model (5) is highly statistically significant and has an adjusted R2 of 76.86 per cent.
To more comprehensively evaluate the relative explanatory power of Models (1) to (5), we augment the ensuing analysis of adjusted R2 measures with a consideration of AIC values, with both measures included in Tables 4 and 5. We do this as, even though the response variable in all models is identical and, therefore, a comparison of their R2 values is meaningful, this goodness-of-fit measure is deficient insofar as it fails to adequately consider entropy as well as a model's fit. Consequently, we also undertake a comparison of models’ AIC estimates, which have the added benefit of greater suitability in large samples. Examination of R2 and AIC values reveals that Models (1) to (5) are of increasingly good fit, as evidenced by a marked increase in the former and decrease in the latter. Moreover, the inclusion of both fundamental and technical analyses in valuation models sees an increase in R2 measures relative to Models (1) to (3), and an a corresponding drop in AIC values.
Despite the preceding discussion, the critical question is whether fitting a hybrid model sees a statistically significant improvement in the ability to explain contemporaneous price relative to fitting models comprising either fundamental or technical factors in isolation. An answer is provided via consideration of the likelihood ratios reported in Table 6. A comparison of these ratios confirms that hybrid models provide a statistically significant increase in explanatory power relative to fundamental or technical models. In further robustness testing, we rerun the regressions outlined in Table 6, using change in price as the dependent variable (see e.g. Beaver et al., 1980; Barth et al., 1990). Inferences regarding the complementary nature of fundamental and technical analysis remain unchanged, although the explanatory power of the resultant models is markedly lower. Taken as a whole, our findings not only reveal the complementary nature of fundamental and technical information, but serve to highlight the benefits of including both analyses in equity valuation exercises.
Unrestricted model | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
(2) | (4) | (5) | ||
Restricted model | (1) | 4 261*** | 34 110*** | 34 925*** |
(2) | 30 664*** | |||
(3) | 1 175*** | 1 990*** | ||
(4) | 815*** |
- *** denotes significance at the 1 per cent level. Notation used in equations (1) to (5) is as follows: Pt+1 is the firm's end-of-month share price in the month forecast earnings for the coming fiscal year are announced. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; Pt–5 is the firm's end-of-month share price 6 months prior to that denoted by Pt+1. This share price is adjusted for capitalization changes; BVPSt is the book value per share of the firm's equity, calculated as at the end of the most recent fiscal year and adjusted for capitalization changes; EPSt is the earnings per share of the firm, calculated at the end of the most recent fiscal year, announced to the market in month t and adjusted for capitalization changes; FEPSt+1 is the consensus forecast earnings per share for the firm, as forecasted in the month following the release of actual earnings per share figures for the most recent fiscal year. Forecast earnings are adjusted for capitalization changes and are announced in the middle of the month, although the exact date varies slightly; DUp is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the stock performed in the top decile in the 6 month period commencing 1 year prior to the measurement of Pt+1, and 0 otherwise; and DDown is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the stock performed in the lowest decile in the 6 month period commencing 1 year prior to the measurement of Pt+1, and 0 otherwise.
5. Concluding remarks
The extant valuation literature invests considerable effort in assessing the ability of both fundamental and technical analyses to explain share prices. However, in doing this, the literature invariably focuses on one type of analysis without reference to the other. Consequently, the literature neglects the possibility that fundamental and technical analyses could serve as complements rather than substitutes in equity valuation exercises. In bridging this gap in the literature, we propose an equity valuation model integrating both fundamental and technical measures. Testing confirms the complementary nature of fundamental and technical analysis by showing that, although each performs well in isolation, models integrating both have superior explanatory power: The integration of both analyses in equity valuation models sees considerable increases in adjusted R2 values and marked drops in corresponding AIC figures, with the significance of our results further verified by the highly significant results of likelihood-ratio testing. Finally, although our findings relate to valuing shares, the complementary nature of fundamental and technical analysis has implications in the context of other valuation exercises.