Volume 45, Issue 4 pp. 429-454
Full Access

Incentives for Non-Disclosure by Corporate Groups

MICHAEL BRADBURY

MICHAEL BRADBURY

School of Accountancy at Massey University

Search for more papers by this author
GRAEME DEAN

GRAEME DEAN

Faculty of Economics and Business, The University of Sydney

Search for more papers by this author
FRANK L. CLARKE

FRANK L. CLARKE

The University of Newcastle

Faculty of Economics and Business, The University of Sydney

Search for more papers by this author
First published: 25 November 2009
Citations: 6
Michael Bradbury ([email protected]) is a Professor in the School of Accountancy at Massey University; Graeme Dean a Professor of Accounting in the Faculty of Economics and Business, The University of Sydney; and Frank L. Clarke an Emeritus Professor of Accounting, The University of Newcastle, and Honorary Professor of Accounting in the Faculty of Economics and Business, The University of Sydney

The comments from Demetris Christodoulou, Gunter Gebhardt, Jane Hamilton, Andrew Jackson, Stewart Jones, Christian Leuz, Joshua Ronen, Mark Russell, Alfred Wagenhofer, and the participants at workshops at the University of Sydney, QUT, La Trobe University; the EAA 2006 annual conference (Dublin), the AFAANZ 2006 annual conference (Wellington), UTS 2007 Summer workshop and the September, 2007 4th International Workshop on Accounting & Regulation (Siena), Stockholm School of Economics Seminar 2009. An ARC Discovery Grant provided financial support for the data collection stages of this project.

Abstract

A regulatory approved deed of cross guarantee (the deed) was introduced into Australia in December 1991, relieving participating companies within a group from having to prepare, have audited, and file financial statements. We examine the characteristics of firms that obtain relief from filing (and therefore disclosing) separate financial statements of closed-group companies by adopting the deed. This is the first attempt to analyse adoption using large-scale archival data. The results support the survey evidence in Dean and Clarke (2005), thus providing triangulation on their work. In particular they support the view that the decision to adopt the deed is a function of strategic factors as well as accounting and auditing cost savings. Those strategic factors were not in focus when regulators first introduced a deed of indemnity in 1985, nor when the original indemnity was modified to become a deed of cross guarantee in 1991 or when it was further modified in 1998. Further, evidence is provided to test the conflicting ideas arising from the analytical literature and the mixed results in the empirical, voluntary disclosure literatures. That evidence suggests that non-disclosure arises when firms are in a more competitive industry and, in particular, when there is ability to retain non-disclosure at the consolidated level (i.e., where the number of segments is high). Other factors supporting non-disclosure are leverage and the proportion of foreign operations (proxying for deed complexity). The proportion of outside directors (a proxy for legal liability) and the number of shares outstanding (a proxy for agency costs of equity) are not associated with the decision to adopt the deed.

Legislation was introduced in Australia in December 1991 relieving participating companies from having to prepare, have audited, and file with the corporate regulator the financial statements of nominated companies within a group. The participating companies are defined as the closed group. The quid pro quo for this filing exemption was that a regulatory administered (prior to 30 June 2004, the regulator also approved) deed of cross guarantee (the deed) must be executed. The deed requires mutual guarantees among closed-group companies of each others' debts when crystallized in the light of any shortfall in a liquidation of any closed-group company. This article examines the characteristics of a cross-section sample of firms that have adopted the deed, thereby obtaining relief from filing and disclosing the separate financial statements of closed-group companies.

The article provides several contributions. It addresses the sparsely explored issue of non-disclosure incentives for corporate groups, drawing on the circumstances related to a novel financial instrument, the Australian deed of cross guarantee. Systematic evidence is elicited to identify the incentives for non-disclosure by corporate groups when a deed is executed. This evidence confirms strategic factors not discussed by regulators either when a form of the deed was first introduced in 1985 or when it was modified in 1991 and 1998. Further, evidence is provided to test the conflicting ideas arising from the analytical and the mixed results in the empirical, voluntary disclosure literatures.

In deciding whether to realize the direct reporting, audit and proprietary cost benefits of non-disclosure by executing the deed, the directors must trade-off these benefits against the potential costs of non-disclosure (i.e., the capital market incentives for disclosure) such as cost of capital and agency cost incentives. They must also contemplate the impact of the deed on the loss of organizational flexibility and the potential increase in legal liability consequent upon the giving of mutual cross guarantees.

Prior research on the deed has focused on modelling the ex post affect of the purported relief provided to creditors in cross-holding situations (Dean et al., 1993; Clarke et al., 1995; Houghton et al., 1999) and surveys of executives about the deed's functions (Dean and Clarke, 2005; Dean et al., 2008). This is the first archival article to examine the determinants of deed adoption. It examines the deed adoption for a sample of 155 non-financial firms listed on the Australian Stock Exchange in 2002. The year 2002 is chosen so that our results can triangulate the perceptions of deed adoption (provided by prior survey research) with actual firm specific characteristics from a large sample of firms.

If the perceptions of deed adoption reported in survey research are reliable then the archival data in this study provide an empirical test for theories relating to voluntary disclosure (or non-disclosure). In particular, evidence is provided to test the conflicting ideas arising from the analytical and the mixed results in the empirical, voluntary disclosure literatures (see Verrecchia, 2001, and Healy and Palepu, 2001, for summaries). Accordingly, we draw on empirical research that relates to the voluntary disclosure of segment data (e.g., Bradbury, 1992a; Harris, 1998; Leuz, 2004; Botosan and Standford, 2005; Berger and Hann, 2007). We also rely on the research that examines the role of cross guarantees in the development of consolidated financial reporting (e.g., Francis, 1986; Whittred, 1986, 1987; Mian and Smith 1990).

The results indicate that the firms that lower disclosure by adopting the deed (53 per cent of our sample) are largely driven by reporting (accounting and auditing) cost savings. Also, there is evidence that proprietary costs lower disclosure. Lower disclosure is found to arise when firms are in a more competitive industry and, in particular, when there is ability to retain non-disclosure at the consolidated level (i.e., where the number of segments is high). There is weak support for deed adoption being related to higher leverage, or having more foreign operations (deed complexity) and a higher market to book ratio (capital market incentives). The proportion of non-executive directors (a proxy for litigation costs) and the number of shares outstanding (a proxy of agency costs of equity) are not significant determinants of deed adoption.

INSTITUTIONAL SETTING

Public and ‘large’ proprietary companies are required by the Australian Corporations Act 2001 to prepare and lodge audited financial statements with the corporate regulator, the Australian Securities and Investments Commission (ASIC). Financial statements filed with ASIC must fully comply with Australian accounting standards and are in the public domain. This reporting requirement applies to the filing of the parent's (separate) financial statements, the group's (consolidated) financial statements, and any sub-entity's (either a subsidiary's separate or sub-group's consolidated) financial statements.

ASIC exempts subsidiary companies from the requirement to file financial statements, if they enter into a deed of cross guarantee. It prescribes:

All the entities seeking relief must be included in the deed, along with any entity which holds shares, either directly or indirectly, in those entities seeking relief. But, if a ‘stand alone’ wholly-owned entity does not require relief, it need not be included. For example, in Figure 1, if company D seeks relief, then A, B, C and E must be included in the deed. Company F is not required to be included in the deed if it does not require relief. If company C requires relief, only A, B, and C need be party to the deed.

Details are in the caption following the image


HYPOTHETICAL ORGANIZATION STRUCTURE USED TO DISCUSS CLOSED GROUPS
Source: Australian Securities and Investments Commission (2009)

However, it should be noted that additional information in the form of closed-group financial statements (financial position and financial performance) is mandated.

Importantly, during the sample period executing the deed is a voluntary decision of the directors of closed-group companies. The deed must be signed by two directors of each closed-group company and the application for relief to the regulator must include, amongst other things, a solvency statement for each company and a diagram showing the structure of the closed group.

The quid pro quo for this financial reporting relief is that each company in the closed group is required to guarantee ‘debts’ of each of the other closed-group companies. The declared objective of the guarantee is to offer protection to all the creditors of each closed-group company. To that end ASIC states:

The deed of cross guarantee makes the group of companies that are parties to that deed akin to a single legal entity in many respects. Creditors and potential creditors can then focus on the consolidated position for those entities rather than the individual financial statements of the wholly-owned subsidiaries that are parties to the deed. (ASIC, 2009, emphasis added)

In its initial promotion of the deed the ASC noted in 1992 that although the separate financial statements of closed-group companies are required for the consolidated financial statements of the whole group, and are routinely produced and readily available, frequently the additional statutory disclosures (e.g., related party transactions disclosures, deferred tax notes, cash flow statements) are considerable. Furthermore, the cost of auditing under the deed is likely to be lower because the materiality criterion for each closed-group company is set at the closed-group level. A recurring claim of the regulator is that accounting and auditing relief constitutes a substantial cost saving to the members of a closed group. Thus the deed is viewed as a means of reducing the financial burden of excessive disclosure regulations for groups (Bosch, 1990, p. 58).

For more than a decade the average size of closed groups is around ten companies per deed (Ramsay and Stapledon, 2001; Dean and Clarke, 2005; van der Laan and Dean, forthcoming). However, the distribution is skewed, with Dean and Clarke noting that the four largest closed groups comprised 162, 126, 104 and 95 subsidiaries as at the end of 2002. At the other end of the distribution there is a high frequency of deeds with only two companies. This evidence suggests there is a sufficient variety in deed adoption practices, especially amongst large firms.

HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT

This study investigates the firm's decision to reduce separate financial statement disclosures. Hypotheses are developed from (a) the decision to obtain relief from filing the audited financial statements of individual subsidiaries with the regulator, and (b) the decision to enjoy this non-disclosure by executing a statutory approved deed of cross guarantee.

With regard to the directors' decision to reduce the level of disclosure, we first consider the potential reporting and auditing cost savings arising from the non-filing of financial statements. Out-of-pocket cost savings are the ASIC-stated reasons for introducing the relief from filing. We then consider proprietary costs of disclosure, of which there is little empirical evidence (Healy and Palepu, 2001). The relief from filing ensures that competitors will not have access to individual company financial statements and will therefore have to rely primarily on segment data reported in the group's consolidated financial statements. We also consider the capital market and agency cost incentives to disclose information. With regard to the decision to execute the deed, negative factors are also considered, namely the potential litigation risk of the directors and the organizational consequences of undertaking cross guarantee (Dean and Clarke, 2005).

Reduction in Reporting and Auditing Costs

The major purported reason for the adoption of the deed is the reduction of the firm's direct (out-of-pocket) reporting costs. Subsidiaries in the closed group do not have to prepare, have audited and file an annual report with the corporate regulator. Dean and Clarke (2005) pose the counter view that each subsidiary in the closed group will still produce financial statements, as these are necessary for internal reporting purposes (i.e., managerial control) and external reporting purposes (i.e., as the foundations for the preparation of the economic group's consolidated statements). ASIC stated that the ‘no filing’ requirement would eliminate the need for certain statutory disclosures at the individual firm level (e.g., related party disclosures and cash flow statements) and the audit may be undertaken using group materiality considerations, thereby reducing the scope and cost of the audit.

The reporting and audit cost savings are likely to be related to lower audit fees. In our cross-sectional design, we are unable to identify the audit fees prior to the deed being in place. Consistent with other empirical studies, firm size has been used as a proxy for the ‘economies of scale’ related to voluntary disclosure (e.g., Firth, 1979) and voluntary interim reporting (Bradbury, 1992b). However, drawing on the regulator's primary reasoning for deed adoption, the cost savings are likely to be related to the number of subsidiaries, rather than size per se. Therefore, the log of the number of subsidiaries (NSUB) is used as a proxy for the potential audit and filing savings arising from adoption of the deed.

Proprietary Costs (and Competition)

One likely reason managers object to providing segment data is that their disclosure would give competitors commercially sensitive information (e.g., see Sprouse, 1969, and Ettredge et al., 2002). Verrecchia (2001) notes, for example, that results from the analytical literature are highly sensitive to specific, often stylized, assumptions. For example, Darrough and Stoughton (1990) argue that greater competition will increase disclosure to discourage entry into the product market. In contrast, the existence of proprietary costs provides a theoretical rationale for less disclosure (e.g., Verrecchia, 1983; Wagenhofer, 1990). Darrough (1993) shows that both the type of information (demand versus cost) and the nature of competition (Cournot versus Bertrand) influence managers' disclosure preferences. Hence, the relationship between voluntary disclosure and competition is likely to be context specific.

The decision to eliminate the level of sub-entity disclosures by adopting the deed is a different setting from the assumptions employed in the theoretical models of voluntary disclosure. For example, theoretical models often assume that managers' disclosure decisions are conditional on the observed signals of firm performance. On the other hand, the decision to adopt the deed (generally) produces a more permanent arrangement and is unlikely to be conditional on the immediate financial performance of subsidiaries. We therefore turn to the empirical literature that relates competition to accounting policy choice.

One of the first studies to include a competition explanatory variable in an empirical analysis is Hagerman and Zmijewski (1979). They examine the impact of competition, with other factors, on accounting policy choices for depreciation, inventory, pension costs and investment credit. Their hypothesis is that the more concentrated the industry, the greater the likelihood of either anti-trust action (a political cost) or rivals' entry into the industry and hence the greater incentive to choose an accounting method that reduces reported profits. Evidence of a negative relationship between the concentration ratio (a proxy for market power) and income increasing accounting policy choices was found.

Bradbury (1991) also uses a concentration ratio to explain the level of voluntary interim reporting, arguing that the costs of accounting disclosure include the impact of entry decisions by potential competitors, and the short-run decisions of existing competitors. As the number of participants increases, the market becomes more competitive and the share of the industry supplied by a firm decreases. Where an industry comprises numerous firms, it is likely that producers will ignore the effect of rivals' actions on their pricing and output decisions. Hence, the cost of disclosing competitive information is likely to be higher in the more concentrated industries. Bradbury finds univariate evidence of a weak negative relationship between the concentration ratio and the level of disclosure.

Scott (1994) argues that information in pension plan disclosures by Canadian firms is proprietary with respect to labour unions. He uses strike incidence, pay rate and return on assets relative to the industry to measure proprietary costs of pension disclosures. The results are consistent with the view that disclosure is a trade-off between proprietary costs and capital market benefits.

Harris (1998) and Leuz (2004) examine the relationship between competition and segment disclosures. Harris shows that the decision to report operations in a given industry as a segment is a function of two measures of industry competition: the four-firm concentration ratio and the speed of abnormal profit adjustment. Her results, consistent with Hayes and Lundholm (1996), suggest that firms with high-profit operations will hide these from competitors using the discretion in segment reporting standards. Leuz finds that capital intensity, as a proxy for entry barriers, is positively related to the level of segment disclosure.

Bhoraj et al. (2004) and Bradbury and Hooks (2005) examine voluntary disclosures in a reorganization of the electric utility industry. Bhoraj et al. measure disclosure during the electric utility industry's transition towards deregulation. They find evidence of capital market incentives positively related to disclosure. Product market incentives are perceived to play a role in disclosure, but only after regulatory concerns have been resolved. Bradbury and Hooks show that disclosure levels decreased when the electric utility industry in New Zealand was reorganized to introduce product market competition. In particular, they find lower disclosures for segment data, forward-looking data and current operating data relating to the firm's derivative positions. They also note that the lower disclosures are temporary and are partially offset from a demand for higher disclosures by capital market agents.

Further empirical evidence of a relationship between competition and proprietary disclosure is provided by Verrecchia and Weber (2006). Investigating ‘redacted proprietary information’ when the SEC grants a firm's request to withhold information from its material contract filings, they find there is an increase in adverse selection (measured by bid-ask spread, market depth and share turnover). Firms are found to be less likely to withhold information when issuing long-term debt and when they are in a competitive industry or experience losses.

In summary, the theoretical models imply that proprietary costs are a major influence on the level of voluntary disclosure. The empirical literature indicates that other incentives for increased disclosure (e.g., capital market, agency costs and regulatory costs) are likely to dominate. However, most of the empirical research is concerned with an increase in voluntary disclosure. The closest scenario to our study of non-disclosure is Verrecchia and Weber (2006). Based on their results, we hypothesize, ceteris paribus, that decisions to reduce proprietary information are likely to be more frequent for firms in competitive industries (i.e., those industries, generally, with lower concentration ratios).

We measure market concentration (and the proprietary costs of disclosure) using the ranks of a four-firm concentration ratio (rankCR4) estimated from all firms listed on the Australian Stock Exchange. The industry sectors comprise between nine and 376 firms with a median of 47.

There is doubt over whether the industry concentration ratio variables proxy for the proprietary costs of disclosure (i.e., non-disclosure of segment data to hide high margin activities) or management deceit (i.e., non-disclosure of segment data to hide low margin activities). Botosan and Stanford (2005) and Berger and Hann (2007) exploit the change in the segment reporting standard (from SFAS 14 to SFAS 131). Botosan and Stanford examine a sample of firms that had previously reported as a single-segment firm and initiated segment disclosures with SFAS 131. They find these firms use the latitude in SFAS 14 to hide profitable segments operating in industries that are less competitive than the primary industry. There is no evidence that firms use SFAS 14 to mask poor performance. Berger and Hann use segment profitability (rather than industry or firm level profitability). ‘Old’ (SFAS 14) and ‘new’ (SFAS 131) segment reports yielded opposite predictions for the agency and proprietary costs motives to disclose segment information. Firms were found to withhold segment disclosures of segments with low abnormal profits (the agency cost hypothesis), and there was mixed evidence supporting the withholding of abnormal profit segment data (the proprietary cost hypothesis).

We do not have the data to address the issue of conflicting agency cost and proprietary cost hypotheses for non-disclosure. As discussed in note 9, the deed is arguably a more permanent arrangement, and therefore current performance (either good or bad) is less likely to be a determinant of non-disclosure. Furthermore, management is unlikely to put loss making subsidiaries in the closed group because, with cross guarantees in place, such a strategy might bring down other companies within the closed group. Hence, our competition variable is considered to proxy for proprietary costs of disclosure.

Finally, the more operating segments the firm has, the greater its ability to mask the performance of competitive businesses within the closed-group companies, either through segment identification or cost allocation (see Hayes and Lundholm, 1996, for a theoretical analysis). That is, for the non-disclosure of proprietary costs to be successful under the deed there must also be non-disclosure under segment reporting. This suggests a need to capture the interaction between the proprietary costs (rankCR4) and the number of segments (NSEG).

Capital Market Incentives

Several analytical papers model the voluntary disclosure decision as a trade-off between capital market benefits and proprietary costs (e.g., Verrecchia, 1983; Hayes and Lundholm, 1996). Pressure from analysts may influence a firm's reporting choices. For example, Lang and Lundholm (1996) and Healy et al. (1999) find an increase in analysts' following after increased disclosure. Several studies (e.g., Choi, 1973; Gibbins et al., 1990; Lang and Lundholm, 1993) support the view that firms increase disclosures prior to issuing new securities. Leuz (2004) employs a dummy variable to indicate a forward-looking equity offering, which is not significant in explaining the level of segment reporting. Verrecchia and Weber (2006) investigate a firm's decision to redact information (presumably proprietary information) from its Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) material contract filings. They argue redaction exacerbates adverse selection, thereby increasing the extent to which market participants will price-protect, finding that firms are more likely to redact information when they are in a competitive industry or suffering losses, less likely to redact information when they issue debt.

This study employs a cross-sectional sample likely to capture the more long-term characteristics of capital market incentives to disclose information. Evidence of long-term capital market incentives for increased disclosure is provided by Frankel et al. (1995). There is a long-term association between the issuance of management forecasts and the raising of external finance. However, forces such as legal liability deter firms from issuing more frequent forecasts around the time of finance offerings. To capture the long-term characteristics of capital market incentives for increased disclosure, market to book equity ratio (MKTBK) is used. MKTBK is a measure of growth, proxying for future financing needs, and is expected to be negatively related to the decision to reduce disclosures (Leuz, 2004). Leuz et al. (2007) provide evidence that ‘going dark’ (i.e., those companies that deregister common stock, thereby suspending or terminating their obligation to comply with SEC reporting requirements leaving shareholders without access to information) is a response to financial difficulties and deteriorating growth opportunities.

Agency Cost Incentives

Watts (1977) uses an agency cost framework to explain the production, and the cross-sectional variation in the content of financial statements. Empirical evidence supports this claim for interim reporting frequency (Leftwich et al., 1981) and the level of interim reporting disclosures (Bradbury, 1991, 1992b).We consider the potential increase in agency costs of equity and debt on the decision to reduce disclosures.

Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue that agency costs increase as the level of outside equity increases. Furthermore, firms with dispersed ownership are more likely to use public disclosures to communicate information. Following Leftwich et al. (1981), Bradbury (1991) and Leuz (2004), the log of the number of outstanding shares (NSHARES) is used to capture the agency costs of equity. Theory suggests there is a negative relationship between NSHARES and the decision to reduce disclosures by adopting the deed. Given that shareholders have access to the consolidated financial statement of the whole group, it is unlikely that the agency costs of equity will be important for the deed adopting firms.

The agency problems of debt are likely to increase as leverage increases. Voluntary disclosures are often hypothesized to be positively associated with leverage. The results of studies are mixed—with some finding a positive relationship between leverage and segment disclosures (e.g., Bradbury, 1992a; Mitchell et al., 1995), and others a negative one (e.g., McKinnon and Dalimunthe, 1993) or none (Leuz, 2004).

An additional benefit of the mutual cross guarantee under the deed is that it potentially facilitates debt contracting. First, the assets of the closed group are pooled in the event of a liquidation of a closed-group company (i.e., where a closed-group company is unable to meet its debts and is put into formal liquidation), and therefore there is more ex ante certainty and diversification of security for creditors. Second, it allows the entity to contract with a single set of lenders to the closed group thereby reducing the financing costs of negotiating with multiple lenders to multiple subsidiaries. While we do not have data to estimate the negotiation costs of financing incurred by the entity, if the cost of debt negotiation under the deed is lower, then firms with the deed in place would likely have more debt than non-deed companies (Whittred, 1987). Leverage (LEV) is estimated by the ratio of debt to total assets.

Directors' Liability

Early commentaries predicted a declining popularity of the deed, as the extent of directors’ legal obligation to certify the financial integrity of the closed group (as described earlier) became more apparent (Hill, 1992, 1995). The additional directors’ liability is created by the additional solvency declarations required by the deed. However, if the deed is a more efficient business decision that lowers costs, then the probability of failure will be lower.

Prior research also suggests that managers' discretionary disclosure policy is likely to be affected by litigation risk (Richardson, 2001). Empirical evidence on litigation risk affecting the disclosure of bad news is provided by Skinner (1994). While measuring directors' liability is difficult, we consider it is important to include a proxy variable for directors' liability to avoid problems with an omitted variable and the strength of prior concerns over directors' liability. Arguably, the directors' liability is more likely to affect independent non-executive directors who would be reasonably expected to have less knowledge of the firm's internal activities than inside directors. Hence, ceteris paribus, a negative relationship is expected between the existence of the deed and the proportion of non-executive directors on the board (PNED).

Impact of Organizational Structure

The non-disclosure and cross guarantee effects from the deed could be achieved by simply transferring the net assets of subsidiaries to a single company structure (without subsidiaries). In this scenario cross guarantees would be unnecessary. Clearly this solution would entail likely considerable transaction costs (e.g., legal costs and taxes) of reconstructing the group into a single entity. Futhermore, if a single entity is an optimal operating structure, in all likelihood the firm would already be organized in this manner. Hence, the existing group structure (if optimal) constrains the ability of the firm to realize the benefits of non-disclosure by adopting the deed. In particular, we consider the impact of organizational factors relating to central control, vertical integration and complexity on deed adoption.

Chowdhry and Nanda (1994) provide an analytical model to explain why firms will bail out struggling subsidiaries (despite no legal obligation to do so). On the other hand, Robbins and Stobaugh (1973) found that most firms prefer to not guarantee the external debt of their subsidiaries, though firms often provide a ‘moral guarantee’ in the form a comfort letter. It is also significant that parent companies rarely provide statements of non-guarantee, preferring to leave intentions ambiguous to facilitate maximum flexibility (Beranek and Clayton, 1985). Clarke, et al. (2003) report several examples of Australian parent companies ‘letting go’ subsidiaries.

Centrally controlled operations  When cross guarantees are executed, ‘organizational’ costs increase because of the potential for a rogue subsidiary bringing down the whole (closed) group. It is reasonable to hypothesize that entities with more centrally controlled operations are less likely to have problems with rogue subsidiaries and consequently are more likely to form closed groups.

Transaction theory developed by Williamson (1975) and the parallel agency theory (e.g., Jensen and Meckling, 1976) can be used to explain the corporate practice of establishing captive finance subsidiaries (Roberts and Viscione, 2001). We use similar arguments to explain why a firm will enter into a deed.

Vertical integration  The net present value of the firm comprises two parts: the present value of synergistic benefits and the value of ‘pure’ investment (independent of synergistic value). Vertical combinations are more likely to arise from synergistic motives. Vertical combinations are formed to save transaction costs related to supply risk and negotiation costs (Williamson, 1975). Frost (1993) provides legal arguments in support of this reasoning. Furthermore, Klein et al. (1978) argue that the more firm specific the activity, the more likely it will be undertaken internally, rather than subcontracted to an independent firm. Mian and Smith (1990) extend this analysis and argue that operating, information and financial interdependence will increase the probability of reporting the operations of a financial subsidiary on a consolidated basis rather than an unconsolidated basis.

Following Mian and Smith (1990) we hypothesize that managers are more likely to provide financial support for firm specific activities or vertical combinations. Here managers will be likely to support such organizational structures within a deed. Alternatively, conglomerate and horizontal business combinations are likely to receive less support. Accordingly, as the number of business segments increases (i.e., the group structure moves towards horizontal organization) the less likely is the company to adopt a deed.

Complexity of foreign operations  The complexity of operations associated with forming a closed group is likely to increase with the level of foreign subsidiaries included under the deed. Operating in a foreign jurisdiction might require disclosures and accounting requirements that are not required under the deed. Furthermore, the ability to pool assets from foreign operations under the deed is problematic (Mason, 2003) because legal issues differ across jurisdictions. Accordingly, firms with foreign operations are less likely to execute a deed.

The above discussion suggests the need for organizational measures of central control, vertical integration and interdependence, and complexity of foreign operations. This presents a problem because these constructs are not directly observable and are likely to be imperfectly measured by a single individual proxy. Following Gaver and Gaver (1993) and Skinner (1993), we use factor analysis to classify our organizational measures into their underlying structure. This approach allows us to capture the common variance of alternative organizational measures, without introducing multicollinearity into subsequent regressions.

THE MODEL

Our hypothesized relationships can be summarized in the following model:

image(1)

where DEED is 1 if a listed parent firm has executed a deed of cross guarantee (and hence it non-discloses) and 0 otherwise,

  • NSUB is the number of subsidiaries,

  • rankCR4 is a four-firm concentration ratio for each industry,

  • NSEG is the number of reported segments,

  • MKTBK is the market to book ratio,

  • LEV is debt to total assets,

  • NSHARES is the number of outstanding shares,

  • PNED is the proportion of independent (non-executive directors), and

  • ORGANIZATIONAL_FACTORS are the three factors representing the underlying organizational structure, estimated from a factor analysis of organizational variables relating to central control, vertical integration and complexity of including foreign operations in the deed.

DATA AND RESULTS

Data

The initial sample comprises the top 225 companies (by market capitalization) listed on the Australian Stock Exchange. Deed adoption is found to be more likely by large firms (Dean and Clarke, 2005; Ramsay and Stapleton, 2001). We eliminate fifty-six firms in the financial sector, as these have different disclosure requirements and financial structures to non-financial firms. Seven overseas listed firms that are unlikely to be eligible to apply the deed are also eliminated. Following Ramsay and Stapledon (2001), two property trusts and five other firms that do not have subsidiaries are eliminated. Accordingly, the final sample comprises 155 firms, 82 (52.9 per cent) of which have executed a deed. Table 1 summarizes the sampling procedures.

Table 1.
SAMPLE SELECTION
image

Table 2 analyses deed usage by industry. The greatest industry uptake is in the Automobile & Components industry, with 100 per cent of the sample adopting the deed, although only two firms comprise this industry. The next highest is the Food & Staples Retailing sector with an 87.5 per cent uptake (seven out of eight firms). The Utilities industry, with 16.7 per cent uptake (one out of six firms) is the lowest. Table 2 reveals a variety of deed use across a range of industries.

Table 2.
DEED USAGE BY INDUSTRY : Industry classification of the 155 firms in our sample, analysed on the basis of whether the firm has executed a deed of cross guarantee to avoid the disclosure of financial statements of specified subsidiaries.
Industry sector (GICS)a Deed firms Non-deed firms Percentage deed firms /total no. of firms
1010 Energy 5 6.1% 6 8.2% 45.5%
1510 Materials 15 18.3% 14 19.2% 51.7%
2010 Capital Goods 5 6.1% 4 5.5% 55.6%
2020 Commercial Services & Supplies 2 2.4% 6 8.2% 25.0%
2030 Transportation 2 2.4% 4 5.5% 33.3%
2510 Automobiles & Components 2 2.4% 0 0.0% 100.0%
2520 Consumer Durables & Apparel 1 1.2% 1 1.4% 50.0%
2530 Consumer Services 7 8.5% 3 4.1% 70.0%
2540 Media 10 12.2% 6 8.2% 62.5%
2550 Retailing 4 4.9% 3 4.1% 57.1%
3010 Food & Staples Retailing 7 8.5% 1 1.4% 87.5%
3020 Food, Beverage & Tobacco 8 9.8% 4 5.5% 66.7%
3510 Health Care Equipment & Services 7 8.5% 5 6.8% 58.3%
3520 Pharmaceuticals & Biotechnology 2 2.4% 2 2.7% 50.0%
4510 Software & Services 2 2.4% 7 9.6% 22.2%
4520 Technology Hardware & Equipment 1 1.2% 1 1.4% 50.0%
5010 Telecommunication Services 1 1.2% 1 1.4% 50.0%
5510 Utilities 1 1.2% 5 6.8% 16.7%
82 100.0% 73 100.0%
  • a Global Industry Classification Standard.

Organizational Variables

We hypothesize that deeds are most likely to be executed by firms that are centrally controlled, vertically integrated and interdependent, and have few foreign operations. We measure central control by the proportion of parent activities to group activities in terms of assets (PASSET) or debt (PDEBT). Compared to horizontally and conglomerate-based firms, a vertically integrated firm is likely to have its business assets concentrated in fewer business segments. To measure vertical integration, we use the proportion of the major business segment to the total size of the group measured in terms of assets (MSEGA) or revenue (MSEGR). The size of foreign operations is measured by the proportion of foreign segment revenue (FSEGR) or assets (FSEGA).

Arguably, whether revenues, assets or debt measures best capture underlying organizational structure is equivocal. Furthermore, there are likely to be strong correlations among segment data. Thus, factor analysis is used to classify variables according to their underlying structure.

Table 3, Panel A reports the descriptive statistics for each organizational variable. Panel B reports Pearson and Spearman correlations. As expected, there are some high correlations among the variables.

Table 3.
FACTOR ANALYSIS RESULTS OF ORGANIZATIONAL VARIABLES

Panel A: Descriptive statistics of organizational variables for 155 firms selected from the 225 top firms listed on the Australian Stock Exchange

MSEGR MSEGA FSEGR FSEGA PDEBT PASSET
Mean 0.685 0.690 0.228 0.173 0.880 0.724
Std. Devi. 0.242 0.319 0.300 0.255 3.660 0.450
Percentiles
25 0.493 0.462 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.482
50 0.670 0.673 0.052 0.022 0.303 0.666
75 0.922 0.952 0.411 0.266 0.972 0.948

Panel B: Correlation matrix (Spearman correlations below diagonal and Pearson above the diagonal) of organizational variables for 155 firms selected from the 225 top firms listed on the Australian Stock Exchange

MSEGR MSEGA FSEGR FSEGA PDEBT PASSET
MSEGR 0.578 −0.202 −0.197 −0.077 0.115
MSEGA 0.697 −0.004 −0.092 −0.029 0.091
FSEGR −0.305 −0.108 0.734 0.049 0.132
FSEGA −0.317 −0.192 0.848 0.119 0.156
PDEBT −0.027 −0.005 −0.017 0.028 0.047
PASSET 0.119 0.042 −0.010 −0.035 0.425

Panel C: Factor analysis results of organizational variables for 155 firms selected from the 225 top firms listed on the Australian Stock Exchange a

Factor 1 Factor 2 Factor 3 Estimated
vertical integration complexity control communalities
MSEGR 0.934 0.876
MSEGA 0.934 0.876
FSEGR 0.927 0.863
FSEGA 0.912 0.860
PDEBT 0.915 0.840
PASSET 0.443 0.235
  • a We report three factors with eigenvalues greater than 1.0, factor loadings > |0.3| for each variable, and estimated communalities for each variable.
  • MSEGR is the ratio of revenue of the major business segment to total revenue of the firm,
  • MSEGA is the ratio of assets of the major business segment to total assets of the firm,
  • FSEGR is the ratio of foreign segment revenue to total revenue,
  • FSEGA is the ratio of foreign segment asset to total assets,
  • PDEBT is the ratio of parent company debt to group debt, and
  • PASSET is ratio of parent total assets to group total assets.

Panel C of Table 3 shows the results of the factor analysis. There are three factors with eigenvalues greater than 1. These factors explain 76 per cent of the variation in the organizational variables. For each factor only factor loadings greater than |0.3| are reported. The proportion of the major segment assets and revenue load on factor one and we label this factor vertical integration. The proportion of foreign operations in terms of revenues and assets load on factor two. Consistent with our hypothesis, this factor is labelled complexity. The proportion of parent company debt to group total debt and parent company total assets to group total assets load on to the third factor. This factor is labelled control by the parent company over the financing, operating, and information interdependence of the group.

Panel C in Table 3 also reports the estimated communalities (which are equivalent to the squared multiple correlations obtained from the regression of each organizational measure with other organizational measures). The high correlations suggest that the use of factor analysis is appropriate.

Descriptive Statistics and Univariate Tests

Table 4 reports the descriptive statistics and univariate tests of the explanatory variables. A Mann-Whitney U, Z statistic is used to test for differences in hypothesized firm characteristics between those firms with deeds and those without.

Table 4.
DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS OF EXPLANATORY VARIABLES

Panel A: Descriptive information on variables hypothesized to influence the reduction of financial disclosures by adopting a deed of cross guarantee for 73 firms that have not adopted the deed

NSUB rankCR4 NSEG MKTBK LEV LogNSHARES PNED Factor 1
vertical integration
Factor 2
complexity
Factor 3
control
Mean 31 84 2 2.215 0.188 5.412 0.755 −0.074 0.145 −0.059
Std. Dev. 45 46 2 2.506 0.216 1.006 0.142 1.154 1.146 0.621
Percentiles
 25 6 31 1 0.957 0.026 4.844 0.714 −0.361 −0.754 −0.407
 50 18 81 2 1.633 0.137 5.252 0.778 −0.309 −0.549 −0.146
 75 29 126 3 2.475 0.301 6.084 0.857 −0.187 0.806 0.140

Panel B: Descriptive information on variables hypothesized to influence the reduction of financial disclosures by adopting a deed of cross guarantee for 82 firms that have adopted the deed

NSUB rankCR4 NSEG MKTBK LEV LogNSHARES PNED Factor 1
vertical integration
Factor 2
complexity
Factor 3
control
Mean 77 74 3 1.758 0.273 5.775 0.747 0.064 −0.126 0.051
Std. Dev. 114 44 2 1.412 0.202 1.082 0.174 0.847 0.840 1.240
Percentiles
 25 24 31 2 1.129 0.166 4.975 0.667 −0.313 −0.751 −0.401
 50 45 71 3 1.502 0.250 5.786 0.800 −0.180 −0.491 −0.174
 75 108 108 4 2.185 0.338 6.512 0.875 0.030 0.449 0.152

Panel C: A Mann-Whitney U Z statistic (MWUZ) is used to test the statistical significance of the difference between deed (Panel B) and non-deed (Panel A) firms

NSUB RankCR4 NSEG MKTBK LEV LogNSHARES PNED Factor 1
vertical integration
Factor 2
complexity
Factor 3
control
MWUZ 5.479 1.364 3.954 0.194 3.407 2.283 0.486 3.582 0.677 0.322
p-value
(1-tailed)
0.000 0.086 0.000 0.423 0.000 0.011 0.314 0.000 0.249 0.374
  • NSUB is the number of subsidiaries,
  • rankCR4 is the four-firm concentration ratio for each industry,
  • MKTBK is the ratio of market to book equity,
  • NSEG is the number of segments,
  • LEV is debt to market equity plus book debt,
  • NSHARES is the of number of shares outstanding,
  • PNED is the proportion of independent (non-executive directors), and
  • Factors 1 to 3 are the derived factors from a factor analysis of organizational variables (see Table 3).

There are four variables (NSUB, NSEG, LEV and the vertical integration factor) where the difference between firms with and without the deed is significant (at the 0.001 level). Deed firms have more subsidiaries, more reported segments, higher leverage and a higher vertical integration factor. This is consistent with the view that deed adoption is easier for firms with high levels of operating, information and financial interdependence (i.e., they are vertically integrated). Rank of CR4 is significantly different at the 0.10 level. DEED firms are in industries with a lower concentration ratio. This is consistent with firms in competitive industries adopting the deed to lower disclosures because of proprietary costs. Firms adopting the deed also have more shares outstanding (significant at 0.05 level), which is opposite to the predicted hypothesis that firms with higher agency costs will have higher levels of disclosures. We consider that logNSHARES is likely to be proxying for size rather than agency costs of equity. There is no univariate support for deed adoption relating to market to book (capital market incentives for disclosures), the proportion of non-executive directors (a proxy for directors' liability), and organizational factors relating to complexity and to control.

A correlation matrix is provided in Table 5. As expected, factor analysis reduces the correlations among the organizational variables. The number of subsidiaries (NSUB) is highly correlated with several variables (NSEG, MKTBK, LEV, NSHARES, vertical integration factor and the complexity factor). This raises a possible multicollinearity problem, which is addressed in the sensitivity analysis below.

Table 5.
CORRELATION MATRIX OF EXPLANATORY VARIABLES : Correlation matrix (Spearman correlations below diagonal and Pearson above the diagonal) of variables hypothesized to explain the lack of disclosure of financial statements of specified subsidiaries for 155 firms selected from the 225 top firms listed on the Australian Stock Exchange
Log
NSUBS
NSEG rankCR4 MKTBK LEV Log
NSHARES
PNED Factor 1
vertical integration
Factor 2
complexity
Factor 3
control
LogNSUB 0.508 −0.153 −0.305 0.191 0.421 −0.041 0.130 0.093 0.092
NSEG 0.490 0.101 −0.145 0.049 0.393 −0.088 0.160 0.006 0.147
rankCR4 −0.148 0.067 0.083 −0.090 −0.031 −0.095 0.176 −0.061 −0.107
MKTBK −0.268 −0.132 0.151 −0.174 −0.081 −0.004 −0.110 0.134 0.036
LEV 0.269 0.122 −0.063 0.119 0.151 0.177 −0.058 −0.050 −0.198
LogNSHARES 0.435 0.390 −0.028 −0.049 0.093 0.023 0.241 0.146 0.139
PNED 0.058 −0.035 −0.100 −0.155 0.210 0.076 0.048 0.049 −0.055
Factor 1
vertical integration
0.541 0.350 −0.030 −0.242 0.127 0.512 0.147 0.000 0.000
Factor 2
complexity
0.228 0.077 −0.011 0.078 −0.017 0.102 −0.004 0.288 0.000
Factor 3
control
−0.114 −0.002 0.068 0.051 −0.235 −0.053 −0.064 −0.101 0.015
  • NSUB is the number of subsidiaries,
  • rankCR4 is the four-firm concentration ratio for each industry,
  • MKTBK is the ratio of market to book equity,
  • NSEG is the number of segments,
  • LEV is debt to market equity plus book debt,
  • NSHARES is the of number of shares outstanding,
  • PNED is the proportion of independent (non-executive directors), and
  • Factors 1 to 3 are the derived factors from a factor analysis of organizational variables (see Table 3).

Multivariate Tests

(DEED), the binary dependent variable indicates that a logit regression is an appropriate multivariate model. Table 6 reports two models. Model 1 includes all variables and model 2 omits the number of subsidiaries (NSUB). Model 1 explains 77 per cent of deed usage. The results show that the logNSUB variable (proxying for accounting and auditing benefits) is significant at the 0.01 level and the main driver of the deed use. The rank of the concentration ratio (rankCR4), the interaction between rankCR4 and the number of segments (NSEG), the complexity factor are significant at the 0.05 level. Market to book ratio (MKTBK) and the number of shares outstanding (logNSHARES) are significant at the 0.10 level. The coefficient on the MKTBK ratio is, however, opposite to the hypothesized direction. Rather than picking up the need for external financing, the growth option variable is possibly proxying for ‘knowledge’ interdependence (Mian and Smith, 1990). The proportion of non-executive directors (PNED) and the organizational factors relating to complexity and control are not significantly associated with deed use.

Table 6.
LOGIT REGRESSION RESULTS : Coefficients and p-values from parameter χ2 from logit regressions for two models for a sample of 155 firms for the Top 225 firms listed on the Australian Stock Exchange. Model 1 reports the results for all hypothesized explanatory variables. Model 2 excludes log of the number of subsidiaries (logNSUB) from the regression to assess the likely effect of multicollinearity.
Hypothesized sign Model 1 Model 2
Coefficient p-value
(1 tailed)
Coefficient p-value
(1 tailed)
Constant −1.067 0.296 0.655 0.354
LogNSUB + 1.065 0.000
rankCR4 −0.018 0.034 −0.019 0.016
NSEG + −0.223 0.221 −0.013 0.480
RankCR4*NSEG + 0.005 0.046 0.005 0.050
MKTBK 0.186 0.076 0.008 0.471
LEV 1.006 0.194 2.308 0.036
LogNSHARES −0.306 0.098 −0.017 0.466
PNED −0.361 0.395 −0.525 0.332
Organizational factors
 vertical integration + 0.272 0.179 0.222 0.145
 complexity −0.452 0.020 −0.276 0.079
 control + 0.281 0.245 0.220 0.195
Cox & Snell R Square 0.277 0.167
Nagelkerke R Square 0.371 0.224
Correct classifications 77.027 70.370
  • NSUB is the number of subsidiaries,
  • rankCR4 is the four-firm concentration ratio for each industry,
  • MKTBK is the ratio of market to book equity,
  • NSEG is the number of segments,
  • LEV is debt to market equity plus book debt,
  • NSHARES is the of number of shares outstanding,
  • PNED is the proportion of independent (non-executive directors), and
  • Factors 1 to 3 are the derived factors from a factor analysis of organizational variables (see Table 3).

Further insight into non-disclosure is to be gleaned from Table 7, which reports the estimated probabilities of adopting the deed from model 1 at specific points in the distribution of selected explanatory variables. For each variable, observations are ranked and grouped in quintiles. For each quintile the median value for the variable and the estimated probability from model 1 are reported.

Table 7.
LOGIT REGRESSION ESTIMATED PROBABILITIES : Estimated probabilities (of adopting the deed and thereby reducing disclosure) from logit regression (Model 1, Table 6) at specific points in the distribution of selected explanatory variables
Variable Quintile
First Second Third Fourth Fifth
LogNSUB Median 2.080 2.940 3.400 4.030 4.970
(probability) (0.199) (0.456) (0.597) (0.761) (0.885)
rankCR4 Median 14 31 81 108 141
(probability) (0.583) (0.548) (0.521) (0.638) (0.383)
NSEG Median 1 1 3 3 6
(probability) (0.168) (0.582) (0.530) (0.724) (0.883)
LEV Median 0.000 0.120 0.220 0.300 0.410
(probability) (0.239) (0.511) (0.682) (0.586) (0.704)
  • NSUB is the number of subsidiaries,
  • rankCR4 is the four-firm concentration ratio for each industry,
  • MKTBK is the ratio of market to book equity,
  • NSEG is the number of segments,
  • LEV is debt to market equity plus book debt.

For the number of subsidiaries (logNSUB), the probability of deed adoption is monotonic across all quintiles. Hence, the benefits of non-disclosure by adopting the deed are linear. For the concentration ratio (rankCR4) the probability of non-disclosure is constant across the first four quintiles (probability range of 0.521 to 0.638) but drops to 0.383 in the fifth quintile. Hence, it is only when competition is very strong (i.e., where the concentration ratio is low) that non-disclosure is an important determinant. This suggests that future research ought to consider converting the concentration ratio into a dummy variable in order to capture proprietary costs. The number of segments (NSEG) is also nearly monotonic across all quintiles. Hence, it is not simply the existence of competition that drives firms to reduce disclosures at the subsidiary financial statement level, but also the ability to retain non-disclosure in the segment report at the consolidated financial statement level. For leverage (LEV) the impact on deed adoption is evident at the tails. That is, the probability of deed adoption is almost constant from the second to the fourth quintiles (between 0.511 to 0.682). However, when there is no debt there is very little incentive to adopt the deed (0.239) and with high debt the fifth quintile probability is 0.704. For market to book (MKTBK), shares outstanding (logNSHARES) and the organizational factors no obvious pattern exists in the probability of deed adoption (and therefore the results are untabulated).

Sensitivity Analysis

A number of alternative specifications for the explanatory variables are explored. We examine several measures of market concentration; a two-firm concentration ratio based on a four-digit industry classification and equivalent two-firm and four-firm Herfindahl index were estimated. There is a high correlation between these measures (i.e., greater than 0.90) and the results are insensitive to the type of industry concentration measure employed or whether ranks or raw measures are used. We also replaced the concentration ratio with a capital intensity variable as a proxy for barrier to entry. Following Leuz (2004), capital intensity is measured as the ratio of property, plant and equipment to total assets. The capital intensity variable, and its interaction with the number of segments, is not statistically significant at the 0.10 level. In this regression market to book is no longer significant, but leverage is significant at the 0.05 level.

Scott (1994) and Leuz (2004) use trading volume to capture the firm's benefits from providing disclosures to the capital market. Hence, in model 1 we replaced the market to book ratio (MKTBK) with the log of the total number of shares traded in the year 2002 scaled by market capitalization. The trading volume variable is not significant in either the univariate or multivariate tests. The MKTBK variable is a proxy for the financing needs of the firm. That is, a firm that has financing needs will not reduce disclosures because of pressure from capital markets to increase disclosure. In model 1, MKTBK is replaced with ex post indicator variables for the increase in debt and increase in shares outstanding. Neither of these variables is significant at conventional levels. However, their inclusion does increase the significance of the leverage variable to the 0.05 level. There is little change in the significance of other variables.

As leverage (debt capacity) is related to assets in place, which might be industry specific, leverage in relation to industry averages is also measured to show whether the leverage of an economic entity with a closed group is greater than the median leverage for firms in the same industry. The results are insensitive to whether industry adjusted or book denominators are used in estimating leverage.

Each of the organizational factors was replaced with the highest loading variable in each factor. That is, the organizational factors were replaced with the proportion of major segment revenue (MSEGR), foreign segment revenue (FSEGR) and parent company debt (PDEBT). The logit regression has a lower explanatory power and the percentage of correct predications falls to 72.3 per cent. The market to book ratio (MKTBK) and foreign segment revenue (FSEGR) are no longer significant at the 0.10 level.

A concern over multicollinearity was also raised because several strong bivariate correlations among the explanatory variables were observed in Table 5. In particular, logNSUB was correlated with a number other variables. An OLS regression using the same variables as model 1 yielded similar levels of significance as in Table 6 for each of the variables. Variance inflation factors in the OLS analysis indicate that, as expected, there is high collinearity among rankCR4, NSEG and the interaction term. The highest VIF on the remaining variables is 1.7 for logNSUB. Model 2, Table 6 reports the logit regression results with logNSUB omitted. The result for model 2 is similar to model 1, except that leverage is significant and MKTBK is not. The model has a lower explanatory power and classification accuracy and hence is robust with regard to concerns of multicollinearity.

CONCLUSIONS

Dean and Clarke (2005) inferred from an interview survey that executing a class order deed of cross guarantee is a multi-faceted strategic choice. That preliminary work suggests that managers trade off the potential net benefits of non-disclosure (the accounting and auditing cost savings from the relief provided under the deed covenants, the proprietary cost savings, the cost of capital reductions, the agency cost reductions) with the loss of organizational flexibility created by the deed and potential increased legal liability of directors. Their interview survey of twenty-eight firms in the top two deciles of companies listed on the Australian Stock Exchange with deeds in place in 2002 revealed several possible major reasons for deed use—accounting and auditing relief (mean score of 4.2 on a 5-point Likert scale of ‘importance’), confidentiality of data (3.0), and facilitation of capital raising (2.4).

The current study is the first to analyse the determinants of deed adoption using large-scale archival data obtained from reports filed in 2002, the same period as applied in the Dean and Clarke (2005) survey, thereby triangulating their evidence. The contemporary results support the conventional wisdom that the cost savings from not having to report, have audited and file separate financial statements of closed-group subsidiaries is a major incentive of deed adoption. However, with regard to proprietary costs of disclosure, the results also support Verrecchia and Webber (2006). The probability of non-disclosure is found to increase at extreme levels of competition (i.e., low rankCR4 concentration ratios) and where information can be hidden in consolidated segment reports. Whereas much of the prior literature is concerned with the extent to which competition will limit voluntary disclosure, our study shows that firms will actively reduce required disclosures, if appropriate legal mechanisms are available.

In a number of sensitivity tests, weak results provide limited support for a relationship between deed adoption and leverage. Complexity of the group, in terms of the extent of foreign operations, is found to be a barrier to deed use. There is no evidence that potential legal risk of the directors (proxied by the proportion of non-executive directors) is associated with deed use. This is qualified by the recognition that the proportion of outside directors might be a weak proxy for legal costs. Hence, there is scope for further research on whether legal risk acts as an inhibiter to deed adoption. There is no evidence that capital market incentives (market to book) or agency costs of equity (number of shares outstanding) are related to deed adoption.

Overall, given conflicting expectations in the analytical literature on disclosure and mixed evidence from the empirical literature, this work contributes to knowledge by providing another setting within which disclosure issues are examined. Further, it addresses the minimally explored issue of non-disclosure. A tangential benefit emerges from this work. New evidence identifying the existence of proprietary cost benefits to deed adopters is revealed. This will assist Australian policy makers better assess the aggregate costs and benefits of the deed. The possibility of proprietary cost benefits accruing to companies adopting the deed was not stated by regulators as being pertinent when the deed was first mooted.

Footnotes

  • 1 Deed covenants only crystallize when (a) a closed-group entity is actually placed in liquidation, and (b) there is a deficiency of assets relative to liabilities after six months. See Dean et al. (1993, 1999) for a more in-depth coverage of the financial implications of a default distribution under the deed.
  • 2 Using 2007 data, van der Laan and Dean (forthcoming) confirm a similar pattern of deed adoption for the Top 225 ASX-listed companies.
  • 3 ASIC is successor body of the Australian Securities Commission (ASC); effective as of 19 December 1991. At the date of the current study, a ‘large’ proprietary company is one that meets at least two of three criteria: (a) consolidated revenue is $10 million or more; (b) consolidated gross assets are $5 million or more; and (c) fifty or more employees. In 2007 requirements were increased.
  • 4 Relief under this regulation is based on similar relief available to corporate groups since 1985, when a class order deed of indemnity was first available.
  • 5 Australian Securities and Investments Commission (2009).
  • 6 The extent to which this single entity view effectively applies is problematic. See Houghton et al. (1999) and CASAC (2000).
  • 7 To put this in perspective, at the end of 2000 the average number of subsidiaries within the selected ‘top 400’ Australian listed corporate groups is twenty-eight, of which 90 per cent are wholly owned (Ramsay and Stapledon, 2001).
  • 8 We assume that segment reports are less useful to competitors than the financial statements of individual companies because of the limited line items reported in segment data and as the informativeness of segment disclosures can be obscured by defining, aggregating and changing lines of business (AIMR 1993; Smiley, 1988; Pacter 1993), as well as by the problems associated with arbitrary fixed cost allocations across segments. The Australian segment reporting standard is closer to SFAS 14 than SFAS 131 and has, therefore, the potential to mask financial performance (see Botosan and Stanford, 2005; Berger and Hann, 2007). This view was supported by some of the respondents in the survey undertaken by Dean and Clarke (2005).
  • 9 It is unlikely that directors would locate currently bad performing firms in a closed group. Furthermore, a short-term performance focus would imply continuous movement of subsidiaries in and out of closed groups depending on current financial performance. This is not examined here. Previous evidence (Dean et al., 1999) reveals movement, but it is sporadic.
  • 10 A number of sensitivity tests on the measure of market concentrations are reported below.
  • 11 Clarke and Dean (2005) show that in recent decades in Australia it has not been uncommon for all group companies to be liquidated simultaneously.
  • 12 Another way includes the so-called ex ante‘opting-in’ and ‘opting–out’ arrangements (see descriptions in the U.K. Cork Committee Report, 1982, and Australia's CASAC Corporate Groups Final Report, 2000)
  • 13 Note that business segment reports would be required regardless of the type of group structure.
  • 14 Of course the provision of a comfort letter can always be revoked. In Australia in the middle of the first decade of the twenty-first century, Walter Bau, a German parent company, reportedly let loose its Australian subsidiary company, Walter Construction Group (see Buffini, 2005). Of note is GM's 2009 decision to let SAAB, its Swedish subsidiary, go into administration.
  • 15 Australian examples of where the collapse or financial difficulty of one company within the group has created a cascading of obligations and group administration (often liquidation) include: 1970s—Minsec and Cambridge Credit Corporation; 1980s—Hooker Corporation, Adsteam, Bond Corporation and Westmex; new millennium cases—Ansett, HIH, and Patrick Corporation in 2004. See Clarke et al. (2003) for details.
  • 16 Fama (1978) discusses the common ground between the work of Williamson (1975) and Jensen and Meckling (1976).
  • 17 Empirical support consistent with these arguments is found in Beranek and Clayton (1985) who find that divestiture rates among conglomerate combinations are expected to exceed those among vertical combinations.
  • 18 Similar results exist in van der Laan and Dean (forthcoming), which examines a sample of 1,526 firms drawn from the population of ASX-listed companies.
  • 19 Asset, revenue and debt data are incomplete for each dimension. We are able to obtain assets and debt figures, but not revenue, from the parent company balance sheets. For segment data we have asset and revenue figures, but not debt.
  • 20 Factor analysis is used to assess the underlying structure rather than the ‘principal components’ (which is mainly used as a data reduction technique). There is little difference between the results of principal components and factor analysis for our sample.
  • 21 While factor analysis classifies variables according to the underlying correlations, the labelling of these factors is the task of the researcher.
  • 22 PASSET also has a 0.28 loading on factor 1. If we set the criteria to estimate four factors (i.e., eigenvalue > 0.93), then PASSET loads on its own factor and 92 per cent of the variation is explained. However, we have no hypotheses why PDEBT should differ from PASSET and, therefore, do not pursue this analysis.
  • 23 This is more obvious when the NSEG variable is grouped to accord with the number of segments rather than quintiles: number of segments (probability); 1 (0.313), 2 (0.440), 3 (0.549), >4 (0.824).
  • 24 Hayes and Lundholm (1996) suggest speed of profit adjustment is a useful way of characterizing market competition. Unlike Harris (1998), Botosan and Harris (2000) and Berger and Hann (2007), we do not have information to estimate a measure of the speed of profit adjustment and, therefore, cannot employ this variable.
  • 25 We do not have trading volume for two of our firms. To maximize our sample we use the market to book ratio for our main tests.
    • The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.