Institutional attention and investment efficiency
Abstract
This study investigates how institutional investors' attention on the earnings announcement day affects corporate investment decisions. I find that the investment of firms receiving abnormal institutional attention is approximately 1.8 times more sensitive to their stock price than that of others. This effect is more pronounced when institutional investors have greater incentives to produce information and when corporate managers have greater incentives and capability to employ the incremental information contained in the stock price. These findings suggest that attention encourages institutional investors to incorporate private information into stock prices, which provides a useful guide for managers' investment decisions.
1 INTRODUCTION
Attention is a limited cognitive resource. For example, when a person is asked to multitask in a limited time frame, the amount of attention spent on one task decreases the amount available for other tasks (Kahneman, 1973). Such ‘limited attention’ has been analysed in a variety of economic and psychological settings (Corwin & Coughenour, 2008). However, the impact of the attention of institutional investors, arguably the most essential class of investors in financial markets today,1 on corporate decisions is largely unexplored2 (Baker & Wurgler, 2013). This lack of knowledge may be due to the biased assumption that institutional investors are not subject to limited attention. Compared with individual investors, institutional investors are more sophisticated because they can afford to employ research staff and have the privilege to access more timely news and information. However, recent studies find that even professional experts can be exposed to such cognitive constraints. For example, Fang et al. (2014) find that certain mutual funds persistently buy into stocks covered in the media and that these funds are later found to perform poorly. Lu et al. (2016) propose that fund managers who are distracted by personal events (e.g., marital) are associated with significantly lower fund returns under their management. Given that institutional investors are also exposed to limited attention, the questions become: How does limited attention affect institutional investor action and what are the consequences of limited attention? This paper attempts to answer these questions by examining the impact of institutional attention on one of the most important corporate decisions: corporate investment.
Corporate investment decisions are one of the most important corporate decisions, as they have long-term effects on the earning potential and the growth rate of a firm. As such, before making any investment decision, managers pay attention to the trading activities that occur in the secondary financial market to obtain useful information to guide their investment (Bond et al., 2012). The information contained in the stock price is produced by market participants only when they pay attention to the stock. Therefore, whether managers can invest efficiently is related to market participants' attention, such as institutional investors' attention.
Institutional attention may affect corporate investments in two opposite directions. On the one hand, it may improve investment efficiency by encouraging institutional investors to incorporate their own information into the stock price, guiding managers to invest efficiently (managerial learning hypothesis). Taking earnings announcements as an example, if institutional investors pay greater attention to a firm on the earnings announcement date, they would have a greater incentive to research and gain an information edge about the firm. This would increase the amount of information content contained in the stock price. With incremental information, managers can better gauge market preferences and make more efficient corporate decisions, such as investment decisions (Bond et al., 2012).
On the other hand, institutional attention may harm investment efficiency. First, limited attention may amplify the behavioural bias of institutional investors (behavioural bias hypothesis). For example, investors may overweight the information of attention-grabbing events and underweight other information, such as their private information. This misallocation of attention may reduce stock price efficiency, especially when the precision of private information is high (Amador & Weill, 2010). The inefficient pricing process makes the efforts of corporate managers trying to obtain information accurately from the market in vain. That, in turn, hampers corporate investment efficiency. Second, rather than producing new information, institutional investors may simply help transfer managerial information to the market through trading on public information (information mediator hypothesis). Such trading will not influence investment efficiency, as the incremental information incorporated by institutional investors is already known to firm managers. Based on the above argument, institutional attention may have a negative impact (or no impact) on investment efficiency. Since there is no ex-ante clear prediction regarding the relationship between institutional attention and investment efficiency, the net effect of institutional attention on corporate investment efficiency remains an empirical question.
In this paper, I investigate this issue using a sample of US public firms from 2011 to 2018. I measure investment efficiency using investment-Q sensitivity (i.e., the correlation between Tobin's Q and the investment proxy), according to Chen et al. (2007). To capture institutional attention, I follow Ben-Rephael et al. (2017) and calculate it as the abnormal institutional attention3 (hereafter, AIA) received by firms on the earnings announcement day. The AIA measure is constructed based on news searching and news reading activity on Bloomberg terminals, given that most Bloomberg terminal users are institutional investors (Ben-Rephael et al., 2017). To test the impact of institutional attention on investment efficiency, I follow Edmans et al. (2017) by regressing investment on Q and its interactions with AIA. I find empirical evidence that firms receiving more institutional attention on the earnings announcement day are associated with better future investment efficiency. Specifically, I find that the investment of firms receiving abnormal institutional attention is approximately 1.8 times more sensitive to their stock price than that of others.
Next, I identify the channels through which AIA affects investment efficiency: AIA improves investment efficiency by encouraging institutional investors to incorporate their own information into the stock price and guiding managers to invest efficiently (managerial learning hypothesis). To corroborate this mechanism, I first examine the impact of AIA on price informativeness. I find that firms receiving AIA on the announcement day have more informative stock prices. To further support the argument, I conduct three sets of cross-sectional tests. In the first set of tests, I examine whether AIA has a stronger effect among firms where institutional investors have a greater incentive to incorporate their own information into the stock price. Institutional investors have greater incentives to trade on their own information when receiving positive news (Edmans et al., 2015) and when firms have lower analyst coverage (Edmans et al., 2017). As such, AIA should have a greater impact on investment efficiency among such firms. In the second set of tests, I examine whether AIA has a stronger effect among firms where managers have greater incentives to learn from the price. Managers have greater incentives to learn from stock prices when it is difficult for them to obtain useful information from their rivals (Allen, 1993) (proxied by industry concentration level: HHI). This makes them rely more on incremental information contained in the stock price when making investment decisions, resulting in a stronger impact of AIA on investment efficiency. In the last set of tests, I examine whether AIA has a stronger effect among firms where managers are more capable of reacting to incremental information. Managers may only respond to incremental information when they have enough resources to invest. As managers of larger firms and less constrained firms can finance their investments more easily (Bakke & Whited, 2010; Whited & Wu, 2006), the impact of AIA on investment efficiency should be more pronounced among these firms. Consistent with the managerial learning hypothesis, I find that the impact of AIA on investment efficiency is stronger among firms with positive news sentiment, greater analyst coverage, higher HHI levels, lower financial constraint levels and larger firms.
To address the endogeneity issue, I perform four additional tests. First, I conduct an instrumental variable analysis, employing the total amount of earnings announcements released in the market on a firm's earnings announcement day and the expected institutional attention as instruments, to address the endogeneity issue of omitted variable bias and reverse causality. Second, I employ the exogenous return shocks from unrelated industries as negative shocks to the institutional attention received by a firm to estimate the causal relationship between AIA and investment efficiency. Third, I employ the Heckman sample selection model to mitigate the sample selection bias caused by unobservable firm characteristics. Last, I repeat the regressions using a propensity score matching (PSM) method to mitigate the sample selection bias caused by observable firm characteristics (Rosenbaum & Rubin, 1983). The results remain consistent with the main finding in all these tests.
I also perform several tests to rule out alternative explanations. An alternative explanation of the findings is that AIA is associated with increased incremental information provided by other market participants (i.e., analysts). As such, managers benefit from the incremental information produced by other market participants instead of institutional investors. To rule out this alternative explanation, I further control for other information sources. Specifically, I control for the amount of managerial information and analysts' information and their interactions with Tobin's Q. I find that the impact of AIA remains positive and significant after controlling for other information sources, suggesting that corporate managers benefit from the incremental information produced by institutional investors. Another alternative explanation of the findings is that the result may confound with the impact of institutional investor ownership. For example, firms with greater institutional ownership may receive more institutional attention on earnings announcement day and institutional ownership may have a direct impact on corporate investment efficiency. If this is the case, the finding may result from a better advising role played by institutional shareholders on investment policies in the firm. To rule out this alternative explanation, I further control for the degree of institutional ownership and its interaction with Tobin's Q. The result remains consistent after controlling institutional ownership.
Finally, I adopt an alternative measure of abnormal institutional attention to ensure that the results are not subject to measurement errors. The measure is constructed using the number of unique requests for firm filings on the SEC EDGAR server introduced by Loughran and McDonald (2014). Compared to individuals who search for information on Google, those requesting information on EDGAR are more likely to be institutional investors. The results remain robust to the use of the alternative measure.
This paper contributes to the literature in three ways. First, it contributes to the growing literature on investor attention. The existing literature discussing the impact of attention focuses mostly on its impact on individual trading behaviour. For example, Schmidt (2019) suggests that distraction hurts asset managers' performance. Compared to non-distracted managers trading in the same stock, distracted managers make poorer trading decisions and incur slightly higher transaction costs. Barber and Odean (2008) propose that individual investors prefer to buy attention-grabbing stocks rather than sell them. While Baker and Wurgler (2013) call for the impact of limited attention on corporate finance to be discussed, the discussion has been mainly theoretical because no firm-level attention measurement is available. This study contributes to this strand of literature by providing empirical evidence of how institutional attention influences corporate investment efficiency.
Second, this study contributes to the long-standing and important debate on whether the financial market affects the real economy (e.g., Bae et al., 2012; Chen et al., 2007). While traditional finance models treat secondary market prices as a sideshow, a growing body of literature demonstrates the importance of stock prices on real decisions. The idea of stock prices being informative and useful to managers' decisions dates back to Hayek (1945). As the financial market gathers information from different investors and ultimately reflects an accurate assessment of firm value through stock prices, managers can learn from this information and use it to guide their decisions. By showing that institutional attention, an essential factor that influences price informativeness, is associated with investment efficiency, my research further supports this strand of literature.
Third, this study also adds to the emerging literature on investor attention and asset pricing dynamics. Engelberg and Parsons (2011) find that local media coverage is associated with the probability and magnitude of local trading by examining the impact of attention and investors' trading behaviour. Yuan (2015) suggests that attention-grabbing events predict the trading behaviour of investors and, in turn, market returns. Da et al. (2011) propose that increased attention from retail investors is associated with higher stock prices in the following 2 weeks and a large first-day return. This study contributes to this stream of literature by showing that price informativeness is significantly affected by the limited attention of institutional investors.
The rest of this paper is organised as follows. The next section reviews the relevant literature and discusses the hypothesis. Section 3 describes the data and the construction of the main variables and summarises the statistics of the data. Section 4 analyses the results, Section 5 provides additional analysis, and Section 6 concludes. Appendix 1 provides definitions and constructions of all the variables used in this study.
2 LITERATURE REVIEW AND HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT
2.1 Determinant of investment efficiency
The neoclassical theory of investment suggests that a firm should keep investing until the marginal cost of investment equals its marginal benefit, assuming that the firm is operating in a perfect capital market without friction (i.e., Abel, 1983; Hayashi, 1982). Empirically, this idea suggests that corporate investment should be driven solely by investment opportunities as measured by Tobin's Q (Tobin, 1969). Since Tobin's Q captures the market's information about a firm's investment opportunities (Hubbard, 1998), the sensitivity of investment (measured by capital expenditure) to Tobin's Q is often used to measure investment efficiency in the finance and accounting literature (i.e., Biddle et al., 2009; Chen et al., 2007, 2011). While Cooper and Ejarque (2003) point out that Tobin's Q could be a noisy measure of investment opportunities, a recent study conducted by Andrei et al. (2019) finds that the classic Q theory of investment works surprisingly well in recent years, suggesting that Tobin's Q may be a better empirical proxy for the firm's investment opportunities than previously thought.
Previous studies find that firms may depart from the optimal investment level due to some imperfections (Chen et al., 2017). One of the major imperfections is the information asymmetry between corporate decision-makers and outsiders. While having an information advantage over the market may prevent managers from investing efficiently (i.e., Myers, 1984; Richardson, 2006), a failure to employ useful information from the market can also lead to the same outcome. This is because managers need to correctly evaluate investment projects to invest efficiently. This requires managers to take into consideration various decision-relevant factors (i.e., customer demand, industrial competition). However, it is highly unlikely for managers to have complete information about every decision-relevant factor. Therefore, making use of information from markets becomes essential for efficient investment. Since markets aggregate information from various sources and reflect it in the stock price, the informative stock price could produce new information to managers that is beneficial to their investment decision (managerial learning hypothesis).
A growing number of studies provide empirical evidence consistent with the managerial learning hypothesis. For example, Chen et al. (2007) provide empirical evidence that managers are influenced by private information in stock prices when they make corporate investment decisions. They find that investment efficiency, measured by investment-to-price sensitivity, increases with price efficiency, measured by price non-synchronicity and the probability of informed trading. Bakke and Whited (2010) offer an econometric methodology to disentangle stock price movements that are relevant for investment so that they can separately test the effects of mispricing and information on investment. Their work further supports the view that managers incorporate information obtained from the price in making investment decisions. Foucault and Frésard (2012) show that cross-listed firms in the US are more sensitive to investment-to-price sensitivity than firms that never cross-list. They argue that cross-listing strengthens price informativeness, which improves investment efficiency by allowing managers to obtain more useful information from market prices. Loureiro and Taboada (2015) find that firms invest more efficiently following firms' adoption of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRS). They argue that the adoption of IFRS improves insiders' ability to learn from market prices, thus resulting in real economic gains. In summary, this preceding research shows that informative stock prices can guide managers to make investment decisions.
In the next section, I will discuss in detail how the attention of institutional investors can affect corporate investment efficiency.
2.2 Attention and investment efficiency
Stock prices can influence corporate investment decisions because they transfer useful information from financial market participants to managers. However, out of the massive volume of information, only those receiving market participants' attention would be processed and incorporated into the stock price through trading (Ben-Rephael et al., 2017). Since attention is a limited cognitive resource (Kahneman, 1973), the degree to which the market price can influence corporate investment decisions consequently depends on the attention given by investors. If investors do not pay enough attention to a firm, the stock prices of that firm will contain less useful information or fail to incorporate available information in a timely manner, reducing the informativeness of stock prices. For example, Gennotte and Trueman (1996) find that stock prices are more informative when an earnings announcement is made during trading hours rather than after the market has closed because investors do not pay enough attention to announcements outside trading hours. Similarly, Dellavigna and Pollet (2009) find that investors are less likely to pay attention to earnings announcements if they are released on a Friday. This leads to post-earnings announcement drift resulting from the underreaction caused by limited attention. Hirshleifer et al. (2009) suggest that investors' reaction to an earnings announcement is weaker, and the post-earnings announcement drift is stronger when the earnings are announced on a day of many competing announcements; and Barber and Odean (2008) find that individual investors' trading decisions are influenced by salient, attention-grabbing events. Overall, the above literature suggests that attention is a crucial factor in determining price informativeness.
If the stock price is not informative, managers may fail to obtain useful information from the stock price to gauge market preference when making an investment decision, resulting in inefficient investment. Based on the above argument, I expect a positive relationship between abnormal institutional attention and investment efficiency (managerial learning hypothesis).
Alternatively, institutional investors may be exposed to behavioural bias (i.e., Coval & Shumway, 2005; Frazzini, 2006; Locke & Mann, 2005). If this is the case, attention may amplify their behavioural bias, thus reducing price efficiency. Since stock prices do not accurately reflect firms' fundamental value, this weakens managers' ability to improve investment efficiency. According to this behavioural bias hypothesis, AIA may weaken or impose no impact on investment efficiency or price informativeness.
It is also possible that institutional investors simply act as information mediators instead of information producers on the earnings announcement day. In this case, instead of producing new information and incorporating it into the stock price, an institutional investor may simply transfer managerial information from firm managers to the market. In other words, institutional investors may trade on firms' public information instead of their private information on the earnings announcement day. If this is the case, the incremental information they incorporated into stock prices would not contain any information that is new to corporate managers. As such, managers cannot benefit from such information when making investment decisions. Based on this information mediator hypothesis, AIA may have no impact on corporate investment efficiency. Therefore, the net impact of AIA on corporate investment efficiency remains an empirical question.
3 DATA AND DESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS
This section describes the data sources and the measurement of the variables used in the empirical analysis and presents the descriptive statistics of the data.
3.1 Data
To examine the effect of the abnormal attention of institutional investors on investment efficiency, I employ a sample of US firms appearing in the Compustat database from 2011 to 2018. The sample period starts in 2011 because the data on AIA have only been available since then. Following Da et al. (2011), I begin with a sample of Russell 3000 stocks. I then remove firm-quarter observations with missing financial data and exclude firms operating in the financial industry (SIC codes 6000–6999) because they are subject to different financial accounting processes, and regulated utilities (SIC codes 4900–4999) because they are more regulated than firms operating in other industries. I also require the stocks in the sample to have measures of news searching and news reading activity on Bloomberg terminals and to appear in the Institutional Brokers Estimate System (I/B/E/S) database. The final sample contains 24,463 firm-quarter observations for 1068 firms over the period from 2011 to 2018.
3.2 Measuring abnormal institutional attention (AIA)
To measure institutional investors' attention, I follow Ben-Rephael et al. (2017) and measure abnormal attention based on news searching and news reading activity for specific stocks on Bloomberg terminals daily. Compared to the Google search volume index first proposed by Da et al. (2011), the news index from Bloomberg terminals can better capture institutional attention. After all, nearly 80% of Bloomberg terminal users are professionals from the financial industry, with the most common job titles being portfolio/fund/investment manager, analyst and trader (Ben-Rephael et al., 2017). This implies that most Bloomberg terminal users are likely to be institutional investors. Bloomberg ranks the news-searching behaviour of users for a specific stock by basing it on the number of times each article is read by its users and the number of times users search for news. Based on the news-searching and news-reading activity criterion, Bloomberg then assigns a score of 1, 2, 3 or 4 (from low to high uses) to each stock on a daily basis. To capture abnormal institutional attention, I follow Ben-Rephael et al. (2017) and generate a dummy variable that is equal to one if Bloomberg's score is 3 or 4 and zero otherwise. This treatment allows us to capture the right tail of the measure's distribution.
While the focus of this paper is to explore the impact of institutional attention on corporate investment decisions, it is important to note that news attracting institutional attention does not necessarily have to be investment-specific to enhance corporate investment efficiency. While news specifically addressing investment may direct attention to a firm's investment policy, attracting institutional investors' attention – even with non-investment-specific news – can spur increased monitoring. This enhanced monitoring effort plays a crucial role in disciplining managers and thereby improving a firm's investment efficiency. For instance, news about an inefficient compensation structure, even unrelated to investment policies, can capture investor attention, prompting intensified monitoring and leading to more efficient investment practices.
3.3 Measuring investment efficiency
Drawing from the literature, I measure investment efficiency by the sensitivity of investment expenditure to investment opportunities (e.g., Chen et al., 2007, 2011). Specifically, I measure investment opportunities using Tobin's Q, calculated as the sum of the market value of outstanding stocks and total liabilities divided by total assets on a quarterly basis. Investment expenditure is measured as a firm's quarterly capital expenditures scaled by the beginning-of-quarter total assets. Because the quarterly capital expenditure variables are reported on a year-to-date basis, I calculate the second, third and fourth quarterly values by subtracting the lagged value from the current value (see Kahle & Stulz, 2013).
3.4 Regression model and variables
Following prior studies on investment (Chen et al., 2007; Zuo, 2016), I also include the following set of control variables: is the quarterly cash flow, measured as the sum of the income before extraordinary items, depreciation and amortisation, scaled by lagged total assets. I include to control the well-documented effect of cash flow on investment (Abel & Eberly, 2011; Lamont, 1997). is the inverse of quarterly total assets (i.e., 1/Asset). I include this variable to isolate the correlation between and induced by the common scaling factor (i.e., ) following Chen et al. (2007).
I include control variables that are found to be correlated with corporate investment (Chen et al., 2017, 2011) or AIA (Ben-Rephael et al., 2017). For example, I include , the ratio of the book value of debt to the book value of assets, to control for the impact of corporate leverage on investment efficiency. As documented by prior studies (i.e., Chen et al., 2011), firms with higher leverage may have more interest expenses and are less likely to obtain additional debt financing, both of which would limit their ability to invest. I also control for , the natural logarithm of firms' market capitalisation, and , the age of the firm, since firm size and firm age are both related to the available resources that a firm can use for investment. Apart from these, I control for , the natural logarithm of the number of analysts covering the stock using the most recent information, as firms with greater analyst coverage are more likely to receive institutional attention (Ben-Rephael et al., 2017). Institutional ownership () and earnings surprise () are also included in the control set as they are important factors affecting the market reaction of an earnings announcement. Firm fixed effects and year-quarter fixed effects are added to control for fixed firm characteristics or time-varying characteristics. Standard errors are clustered by firm to mitigate the statistical concern arising from autocorrelated residuals (Petersen, 2009). All continuous variables are winsorised at the top and bottom 1% levels to reduce the impact of outliers.
3.5 Summary statistics
Table 1 presents the summary statistics of the main variables used in this study. The mean (median) value of AIA is 0.608 (1), similar to that reported by Ben-Rephael et al. (2017) (mean AIA = 0.620; median AIA = 1 around the earnings announcement day), suggesting that most firms receive abnormal institutional attention on the earnings announcement day. The mean and median values of other variables are consistent with prior studies (Ben-Rephael et al., 2017; Kahle & Stulz, 2013). For example, the mean (median) value of Q is 1.978 (1.659), similar to that reported in Chen et al. (2007) (mean = 1.81; median = 1.31).
Variable | N | Mean | SD | Median |
---|---|---|---|---|
AIA | 24,463 | 0.608 | 0.488 | 1.000 |
Inv | 24,463 | 1.168 | 1.355 | 0.729 |
Q | 24,463 | 1.978 | 1.885 | 1.659 |
CF | 24,463 | 0.015 | 0.046 | 0.023 |
Leverage% | 24,463 | 24.298 | 20.709 | 22.324 |
Asset1 | 24,463 | 0.002 | 0.005 | 0.001 |
MrtCap | 24,463 | 7.695 | 1.720 | 7.571 |
Age | 24,463 | 25.202 | 15.246 | 22.000 |
LnNumEst | 24,463 | 2.559 | 0.598 | 2.565 |
Inst | 24,463 | 0.757 | 0.230 | 0.808 |
SUE | 24,463 | 0.045 | 0.068 | 0.024 |
- Note: This table presents the means, medians and standard deviations of key variables for firms in the sample. The sample comprises 24,463 firm-year observations of 1068 unique firms from 2011 to 2018. Detailed variable descriptions are given in Appendix 1.
Table 2 presents the pairwise Pearson correlations for the main variables used in the regression analysis. As shown in Panel B, AIA and Inv are significantly correlated with all of the control variables, suggesting that the control set is valid.
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
AIA | Inv | Q | CF | Leverage | LnNumEst | Age | Size | Asset1 | Inst | SUE | |
(1) | 1 | ||||||||||
(2) | 0.086*** | 1 | |||||||||
(3) | 0.108*** | 0.066*** | 1 | ||||||||
(4) | 0.153*** | 0.177*** | −0.099*** | 1 | |||||||
(5) | 0.222*** | 0.049*** | −0.052*** | 0.042*** | 1 | ||||||
(6) | 0.049*** | −0.017*** | −0.096*** | 0.021*** | −0.006 | 1 | |||||
(7) | 0.080*** | 0.035*** | −0.156*** | 0.194*** | 0.028*** | 0.152*** | 1 | ||||
(8) | 0.532*** | 0.050*** | 0.164*** | 0.299*** | 0.146*** | 0.095*** | 0.275*** | 1 | |||
(9) | −0.264*** | −0.016*** | 0.202*** | −0.490*** | −0.177*** | −0.022*** | −0.142*** | −0.470*** | 1 | ||
(10) | 0.015*** | −0.018*** | −0.058*** | −0.002 | 0.002 | 0.284*** | 0.050*** | 0.021*** | −0.025*** | 1 | |
(11) | 0.011** | 0.010** | 0.055*** | 0.021*** | 0.048*** | 0.008* | −0.013*** | 0.001 | 0.001 | −0.039*** | 1 |
- Note: This table reports the correlations between key variables for firms in the sample. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level. Detailed variable descriptions are given in Appendix 1.
4 RESULTS
4.1 AIA and investment efficiency
Table 3 estimates the impact of AIA on investment efficiency using different models. Specifically, columns (1) and (2) estimate the influence of AIA on investment efficiency in the firm fixed effects model and industry-YearQuarter fixed effects model, respectively, following Bird et al. (2021). In column (3), additional control variables are added to the firm fixed effects model. I find that the coefficient on the interaction term (AIA*Q) is positive and significant across all specifications. This result is consistent with the managerial learning hypothesis that AIA encourages institutional investors to incorporate their information into the stock price, allowing managers to invest efficiently through learning from the price.
(1) | (2) | (3) | |
---|---|---|---|
Dependent variable: Inv | |||
AIA*Q | 0.0388*** | 0.0279** | 0.0245** |
(3.37) | (2.46) | (2.20) | |
AIA | −0.1001*** | −0.0706** | −0.0907*** |
(−3.13) | (−2.21) | (−2.97) | |
Q | 0.0718*** | 0.0579*** | 0.0305* |
(4.24) | (3.92) | (1.96) | |
CF | 1.5035*** | ||
(4.36) | |||
Leverage | −0.0049*** | ||
(−4.22) | |||
Asset1 | 11.1551 | ||
(1.45) | |||
MrtCap | 0.2375*** | ||
(5.34) | |||
vAge | 0.0790 | ||
(0.89) | |||
LnNumEst | −0.0021 | ||
(−0.86) | |||
Inst | −0.0302 | ||
(−0.22) | |||
SUE | −0.1086 | ||
(−0.63) | |||
_cons | 1.0355*** | 1.0628*** | −0.7467* |
(29.19) | (33.03) | (−1.74) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes | No | Yes |
Industry-YearQuarter | No | Yes | No |
Firm | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 24,463 | 22,870 | 24,463 |
r 2 | 0.6783 | 0.7591 | 0.6847 |
- Note: This table presents the relationship between abnormal institutional attention and investment-Q sensitivity. The dependent variable is investment (i.e., capital expenditure). Column (1) shows the impact of abnormal institutional attention on investment-Q sensitivity (AIA*Q). Column (2) presents the impact of abnormal institutional attention on investment-Q sensitivity (AIA*Q) in a PSM setting. Column (3) further controls the impact of the portion of institutional investors on investment-Q sensitivity (Ins*Q). Year-quarter fixed effects and firm fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All other variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
The economic magnitude of the improvement is also significant. The positive and significant coefficient of AIA*Q (coefficient = 0.0245; column (3)) implies that, on average, the investment of firms receiving abnormal institutional attention on the earnings announcement day is approximately 1.8 times more sensitive to their stock price than others. To explain this substantial economic magnitude, consider a one-standard-deviation increase in Q (1.885). This shock is associated with a greater investment for both firms that received abnormal institutional attention and those that did not. However, this impact is stronger for those who received abnormal institutional attention because their investment increased by 10.37% ()*SD(Q) = (0.0305 + 0.0245)*1.885) on average. In contrast, the investment of firms that do not receive abnormal institutional attention increases by 5.75% (*SD(Q) = 0.0305*1.885) on average. As such, the investment of firms receiving abnormal institutional attention is 1.8 times (10.37%/5.75%) more sensitive to stock prices. This result is consistent with the literature. For example, Edmans et al. (2017) find that increasing the amount of outsider information in stock prices can lead to a 38% increase in investment-Q sensitivity; Foucault and Frésard (2012) propose that cross-listing experience doubles corporate investment-Q sensitivity, suggesting that information in financial markets can be essential to corporate investment decisions.
4.2 Investigating the channel
Thus far, the results suggest that AIA is associated with increased investment-Q sensitivity. In this section, I explore the channel through which AIA affects investment-Q sensitivity. According to the managerial learning hypothesis, managers can obtain useful information from stock prices and engage in more efficient investment if the price is informative (Bond et al., 2012; Chen et al., 2007). As such, I argue that AIA improves firms' investment-Q sensitivity by encouraging institutional investors to incorporate more information into the stock price, allowing managers to obtain useful information from the stock price to invest efficiently.
4.2.1 AIA and price informativeness
Columns (1) and (2) of Table 4 report the relationship between AIA and price informativeness (measured as and Ln(), respectively). I find that the coefficient of AIA is positive and significant at the 1% level, suggesting that abnormal institutional attention is associated with improved stock price informativeness. To improve the validity of this test, I estimated price informativeness alternatively from the market model4 following Ferreira et al. (2011). The result is reported in columns (3) and (4) of Table 4. I find the result remains unchanged.
Chen et al. (2007) Model | Ferreira et al. (2011) Model | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
R2 | LNR2 | R2 | LNR2 | |
AIA | 0.0183*** | 0.0996*** | 0.0133*** | 0.0717*** |
(3.18) | (3.16) | (2.73) | (2.70) | |
Q | 0.0087*** | 0.0408*** | 0.0005 | −0.0009 |
(3.87) | (3.42) | (0.29) | (−0.09) | |
CF | −0.0564 | −0.2363 | −0.0628 | −0.3613 |
(−0.69) | (−0.54) | (−1.01) | (−1.07) | |
Leverage | −0.0002 | −0.0011 | 0.0000 | 0.0003 |
(−1.14) | (−1.00) | (0.25) | (0.35) | |
Asset1 | −0.0383 | 0.3555 | 0.2877 | 1.4679 |
(−0.05) | (0.08) | (0.42) | (0.39) | |
MrtCap | −0.0080** | −0.0364** | −0.0048* | −0.0207 |
(−2.33) | (−1.97) | (−1.71) | (−1.37) | |
Age | −0.0026*** | −0.0147*** | −0.0013*** | −0.0071*** |
(−8.23) | (−8.48) | (−5.08) | (−4.99) | |
LnNumEst | −0.0984*** | −0.5453*** | −0.0197*** | −0.1172*** |
(−12.63) | (−12.86) | (−3.36) | (−3.68) | |
Inst | −0.0400** | −0.3134*** | −0.0334** | −0.2834*** |
(−2.23) | (−3.00) | (−2.27) | (−3.39) | |
SUE | 0.1018** | 0.5106* | 0.1922*** | 1.0261*** |
(2.02) | (1.89) | (5.89) | (5.40) | |
_cons | 0.9952*** | 2.7548*** | 0.7779*** | 1.5354*** |
(31.49) | (15.48) | (29.82) | (10.67) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 24,398 | 24,398 | 24,398 | 24,398 |
R 2 | 0.3372 | 0.3154 | 0.2773 | 0.2527 |
- Note: This table presents the relationship between abnormal institutional attention and price informativeness (i.e., R2; LNR2). Columns (1) and (2) present the result in which R2 is the R2 value of the regression following Chen et al. (2007). Columns (3) and (4) present the result in which R2 is the R2 estimated from the Fama–French three-factor model: following Ferreira et al. (2011). is the daily excess return for stock i, is the daily excess return of industry j and is the daily excess return of the market portfolio. Year-Quarter fixed effects and industry fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All other variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
Overall, the result in this section suggests that AIA is associated with price informativeness. Together with the main finding that AIA is positively correlated with investment efficiency, the evidence suggests that AIA improves investment efficiency by increasing the information content contained in stock prices.
4.2.2 Cross-sectional tests
In this section, I conduct three sets of cross-sectional tests to further support the managerial learning hypothesis. If AIA improves investment efficiency by increasing the information content contained in stock prices, allowing managers to make efficient investments by obtaining useful information from stock prices, then the effect should be more pronounced among firms where (1) institutional investors have greater incentives to incorporate their own information into stock prices; (2) managers have greater incentives to learn from prices; and (3) managers are more capable of responding to the incremental information included in stock prices.
Institutional investors' information production incentive
Institutional investors have a greater incentive to incorporate their own information into the stock price when they receive good news of a firm. As documented by Edmans et al. (2015), the feedback effect increases the profitability of buying on good news while reducing the profitability of selling on bad news. Since decision-makers can learn from price changes, they can increase the asset value by making use of these pieces of information. This increases investors' profits from buying on positive information and reduces the profitability of selling on negative information. As a result, investors have greater incentives to incorporate their information into the stock price when receiving good news from a firm.
Given the above discussion, I predict that the impact of AIA on investment efficiency should be more pronounced among firms with positive news sentiment. Firms' news sentiment is calculated according to the percentage of positive news over a rolling 90-day window.5 I then generate a dummy variable PosNews that takes the value of one if the positive news accounts for more than 50% over the 90-day windows and regresses Inv on its interaction with AIA*Q. Table 5 reports the results. As shown in column (1), the triple interaction (AIA*Q*PosNews) has a positive and significant coefficient, suggesting that AIA has a stronger impact on investment efficiency when firms have positive news sentiment.
Dependent variable: Inv | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | |
AIA*Q*PosNews | 0.0204** | ||||
(0.01) | |||||
AIA*Q*Analyst | −0.0321** | ||||
(0.03) | |||||
AIA*Q*HHI | 0.0377* | ||||
(0.05) | |||||
AIA*Q*WW | −0.0359** | ||||
(0.01) | |||||
AIA*Q*Size | 0.0277** | ||||
(0.03) | |||||
Controls & lower order terms | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 24,463 | 24,463 | 24,463 | 23,643 | 24,463 |
R 2 | 0.6672 | 0.6701 | 0.6701 | 0.6677 | 0.6672 |
- Note: This table presents the impact of different elements on the association between AIA and investment efficiency. Columns (1)–(5) present the effect of earnings announcement sentiment, analyst coverage, industry concentration, financial constraints and firm size on the association between AIA and investment efficiency, respectively. Year-Quarter fixed effects and firm fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All other variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
In addition, analyst coverage can also affect institutional investors' incentives to produce information. Specifically, institutional investors would have greater incentives to produce information if the firm has lower analyst coverage. This is because the stock price of a firm with greater analyst coverage is more efficient than those with lower analyst coverage (Chung & Jo, 1996; Kelly & Ljungqvist, 2012). As such, institutional investors profit less from acquiring and producing information from firms with greater analyst coverage, given that most of the information has already been incorporated into the stock price. Therefore, institutional investors would have less incentive to acquire and produce information for firms with greater analyst coverage, reducing the impact of AIA on investment efficiency.
To test this prediction, I define analyst coverage as the natural logarithm of 1 plus the number of analysts in the I/B/E/S database covering the stock using the most recent information. I then assign a dummy variable (Analyst) to firms based on the firm-year-quarter analyst coverage level. Analyst takes the value of one if firms have an above-average analyst coverage level in a given quarter and zero otherwise. Interacting AIA*Q with Analyst, I find that the impact of AIA on investment is less pronounced among firms with greater analyst coverage, as reflected by the negative coefficient of the triple interactions (column (2), Table 5). Overall, the results in this section support the managerial learning hypothesis by showing that the impact of AIA on investment efficiency is stronger among firms where institutional investors have greater incentives to incorporate their own information into stock prices.
Manager incentives to learn from stock price
Managers of firms operating in more concentrated industries should have greater incentives to learn from the stock price. As suggested by Allen (1993), managers of firms operating in concentrated industries have greater demand to learn from stock prices, as they have fewer rivals to learn from. Apart from that, the size and production function of firms operating in concentrated industries are likely to be different, reducing the useful information a manager can learn from rivals. Therefore, the demand for these managers to learn from stock prices is relatively high, increasing the impact of AIA on investment efficiency.
I measure the industry concentration level using the Herfindahl–Hirschman Index, calculated as the sum of the squared market shares of all firms operating in each SIC three-digit industry. I then construct a dummy variable (HHI3) based on the industry concentration level. HHI3 takes the value of one if firms have an above-average industry concentration level in a given quarter and zero otherwise. The result is reported in Table 5. As shown in column (3), the coefficient of the triple interaction (AIA*Q*HHI3) is positive and significant, suggesting that the impact of AIA on investment efficiency is stronger among concentrated firms. Together, the results in this section support the managerial learning hypothesis by showing that the impact of AIA on investment efficiency is stronger among firms where managers have greater incentives to learn from price.
Manager capability to react to the information
Managers can respond more to the incremental information contained in the stock price when they have greater resources to invest. To capture the availability of resources, I employ the following two proxies. The first is the WW financial constraint index (Whited & Wu, 2006). Given that firms with financial constraints are less likely to obtain external resources to finance their investment, managers of these firms would respond less to the information contained in the stock price. The second proxy is firm size. As documented by Bakke and Whited (2010) and Hennessy and Whited (2007), small firms incur much greater financing costs than large firms. Therefore, managers of small firms are less likely to respond to the incremental information contained in the stock price, as it is too costly for them to respond. Since managers of smaller firms and firms with financial constraints are less likely to respond to incremental information, the impact of AIA on investment efficiency should be less pronounced among these firms.
Consistent with the prediction, I find that AIA has a stronger impact on investment efficiency among firms with fewer financial constraints (column (4), Table 5) and larger firms (column (5), Table 5). These results further support the managerial learning hypothesis by showing that the impact of AIA on investment efficiency is stronger among firms where managers have a greater capability to react to the information contained in the stock price.
This finding also rules out the alternative explanation that AIA improves investment efficiency by allowing managers to obtain greater funding in the primary market. If the association between AIA and investment efficiency results from an increase in the ability to access funds in the primary market, the results should be more pronounced among firms with higher financial constraints, contrary to what I found. Overall, the findings in the cross-sectional test section suggest that AIA improves investment efficiency by improving stock price informativeness, allowing managers to learn from price and invest efficiently.
5 ADDITIONAL TESTS TO ADDRESS THE ENDOGENEITY CONCERN
5.1 Instrumental variable regressions
To alleviate potential endogeneity from reverse causality or omitted variables, I perform instrumental variable analysis. Specifically, I use NoAnnouncement (number of earnings announcements) and EAIA (expected AIA) as instruments for AIA because they both related to institutional attention and are arguably not related to investment efficiency through any channels other than the attention channel. The choice of the first instrument (NoAnnouncement) is inspired by the idea that it captures the likelihood of institutional investors being distracted by the earnings announcement of other firms. This indicator takes the value of one if the number of competing announcements of a firm is above the firm-quarter median. Indeed, investors' reaction to an earnings announcement is weaker when earnings are announced on a day of many competing announcements due to limited attention (Hirshleifer et al., 2011). Thus, a higher value of NoAnnouncement implies a lower amount of attention being allocated to a specific firm (i.e., the correlation between AIA and NoAnnouncement should be negative). The second instrument (EAIA) refers to the median AIA across the previous four earnings announcements (Chiu et al., 2021). As documented by Ben-Rephael et al. (2021), attention to a firm's past earnings announcements can predict the attention to a firm's current earnings announcements. Therefore, a positive association between AIA and EAIA should be observed.
Column (1) of Table 6 presents the first-stage regression results. Consistent with my prediction, the correlation between NoAnnouncement and AIA is negative whereas the correlation between EAIA and AIA is positive. The significant Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic and Kleibergen-Paap Wald F-statistic reject the null hypothesis that the instrumental variables are weak or under-identified. The insignificant Hansen J statistic suggests that the instrumental variables are not subjected to overidentification. In the second-stage regression, I replace AIA with its fitted values predicted from the first stage and repeat the baseline regression. As shown in column (2) of Table 6, the coefficient of AIA*Q is still positive and significant, indicating that the finding is not driven by unobservable omitted variables or the reverse causality issue.
(1) | (2) | |
---|---|---|
Instrumental variable | ||
First-stage | Second-stage | |
AIA | Inv | |
c.AIA#c.Q | 0.0728** | |
(2.09) | ||
EAIA | 0.2256*** | |
(16.09) | ||
c.EAIA#c.Q | −0.0088** | |
(−2.10) | ||
NoAnnounce | −0.0129* | |
(−1.66) | ||
c.NoAnnounce#c.Q | −0.0007 | |
(−0.23) | ||
AIA | −0.2245* | |
(−1.83) | ||
Controls & lower order terms | Yes | Yes |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes |
N | 24,463 | 24,463 |
R 2 | 0.0277 | |
Under identification test | ||
Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic | 173.638*** | |
Weak identification test | ||
Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F-statistic | 76.984*** | |
Over identification test | ||
p-value of Hansen J statistic | 0.321 |
- Note: This table reports the relationship between AIA and investment-Q sensitivity addressing endogeneity issues using instrumental variable regression, Heckman two-stage selection analysis and PSM analysis. Column (1) reports the first-stage result of the instrumental variable regression using the number of earning announcements (NoAnnouncement) and expected AIA (EAIA) as the instruments. Column (2) reports the second-stage result of the instrumental variable regression. Firm fixed and year-quarter fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
5.2 Exogenous return shocks from unrelated industries
To address concerns related to endogeneity and omitted variables in the findings, I further employ the exogenous return shocks from unrelated industries to estimate the causal relationship between AIA and investment efficiency. As highlighted in the study by Kempf et al. (2017), institutional investors tend to focus more on industries with extreme returns, be they exceptionally low or high.6
To test, I first estimated the industry return for each year-quarter based on the SIC3 industry classification. I defined an industry shock (IS) as a dummy variable, taking the value of one if the return of an industry in a given quarter was located in the top or bottom quartile across all SIC3 industries. Firms were then categorised into treatment and control groups based on the IS of unrelated industries. Specifically, treatment firms (Distraction = 1) were those from industries with non-extreme returns (IS = 0) because institutional investors of such firms were highly likely to be distracted by the extreme returns in other unrelated industries. Conversely, control firms were those from industries with extreme returns (IS = 1). For a more precise analysis, I further exclude those firms that themselves experienced extremely high or low returns (i.e., in the top or bottom quartile across all firms in a specific industry) as the impact of distraction would be less pronounced among such firms.
Table 7 reports the result of the test. The negative and significant coefficient of Distraction*Q indicates that institutional distraction negatively affects a firm's investment efficiency. Importantly, by employing an exogenous shock in the form of industry returns, these findings help alleviate concerns that the main results are driven by omitted endogenous factors.
Dependent variable: Inv | |
---|---|
Distraction*Q | −0.0197** |
(−2.49) | |
Distraction | 0.0325 |
(1.36) | |
Q | 0.0278** |
(2.27) | |
CF | 1.5389*** |
(4.34) | |
Leverage | −0.0053*** |
(−4.11) | |
Asset1 | 1.2010 |
(0.19) | |
MrtCap | 0.2318*** |
(5.18) | |
Age | −0.1260 |
(−1.00) | |
LnNumEst | −0.0015 |
(−0.55) | |
Inst | −0.1291 |
(−0.88) | |
SUE | 0.1190 |
(0.62) | |
_cons | −0.1290 |
(−0.26) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes |
Firm | Yes |
N | 12,028 |
R 2 | 0.7036 |
- Note: This table employs the exogenous return shocks from unrelated industries as exogenous negative shocks to the institutional attention received by a firm to estimate the causal relationship between AIA and investment efficiency. Firm fixed and year-quarter fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
5.3 Addressing sample selection bias
I perform two tests to address the sample selection bias issue. First, to address sample selection bias due to unobservability, I perform Heckman sample selection analysis. In the first stage, I use a probit model to predict the presence of abnormal institutional attention. Specifically, I regress AIA on NoAnnouncement and all the control variables from the baseline regression to predict the inverse Mill's ratio (MILLS). In the second-stage regression, I repeat the baseline regression with MILLS as an additional control variable to control for the self-selection effect. As reported in column (1) of Table 8, the coefficient of AIA*Q remains positive and significant after including MILLS in the regression. The coefficient of MILLS is significantly different from zero, implying the importance of controlling for potential selection bias.
(1) | (2) | |
---|---|---|
Heckman | PSM | |
Second-stage | ||
Inv | Inv | |
AIA*Q | 0.0239** | 0.0246* |
(0.03) | (0.08) | |
AIA | −0.0875*** | −0.0680* |
(0.00) | (0.07) | |
Q | 0.0310* | 0.0151 |
(0.09) | (0.51) | |
CF | 1.6312*** | 1.1474*** |
(0.00) | (0.01) | |
Leverage | −0.0039*** | −0.0055*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | |
Asset1 | 9.1823 | 2.2254 |
(0.30) | (0.78) | |
MrtCap | 0.2950*** | 0.2197*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | |
Age | −0.0009 | −0.0040 |
(0.69) | (0.53) | |
LnNumEst | 0.0004 | 0.0801 |
(1.00) | (0.58) | |
Inst | −0.1498 | −0.2410 |
(0.30) | (0.20) | |
SUE | 0.0723 | −0.1300 |
(0.73) | (0.66) | |
Mills | 0.2245* | |
(0.08) | ||
_cons | −1.1492** | −0.2706 |
(0.05) | (0.64) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes |
N | 20,543 | 9893 |
R 2 | 0.6856 | 0.7030 |
- Note: This table reports the relationship between AIA and investment-Q sensitivity addressing the endogeneity issue related to sample selection bias. Column (1) reports the second stage result of the Heckman two-stage selection analysis and Column (2) shows the PSM analysis result. Firm fixed and year-quarter fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
To address sample selection bias that is occasioned by the correlation between AIA and observable firm characteristics, I also perform the baseline regression in the propensity score matching (PSM) setting. In the first stage, I use a logit model and regress AIA on CF, Leverage, Asset, MktCap, Age and LnNumEst to calculate the propensity score. I then match each treated unit (AIA = 1) with its neighbour (control group: AIA = 0) based on the propensity score. The matching results in a sample of 9893 firm-year observations. Appendix 2 reports the correlation between AIA and all other control variables before and after matching. The insignificant coefficients of the control variables in column (2) suggest that the control group and the treatment group share similar characteristics after matching.
After confirming that the matched sample is valid, I then rerun the baseline regression model on the matched sample. Column (2) of Table 8 reports the results. As reported in column (3), the coefficient of AIA*Q remains positive and significant, suggesting that the baseline finding is unlikely to be driven by the correlation between AIA and observable firm characteristics.
5.4 Other alternative explanations
The evidence is consistent with the idea that abnormal attention encourages institutional investors to incorporate their information into the stock price, which provides useful feedback for managers to invest efficiently. In this section, I perform several tests to rule out the alternative explanation that (1) the information contained in the stock price is from other sources (i.e., analysts, managers) and (2) the results are driven by institutional ownership.
5.4.1 Controlling for other information sources
An alternative explanation could be that the stock price also contains information from other market participants (i.e., analysts) on the earnings announcement days and that the useful information contained in the stock price is possessed by other market participants. To rule out this alternative explanation, I control for information possessed by corporate managers and financial analysts following stocks of the sample companies. Following Chen et al. (2007), I measure private managerial information based on earning surprise (SUE). Earning surprise captures the unexpected return on the announcement day, and therefore, a large earning surprise indicates that investors know less information about earnings. Since managers know the earnings before the announcement day, the earning surprise can capture the information asymmetry between managers and the market. Column (1) of Table 9 reports the regression results after controlling for private managerial information. The coefficient of AIA*Q is positive and significant at the 5% level, consistent with our main finding. The negative coefficient of SUE*Q is consistent with the argument that managers would rely less on information contained in the stock price for investment decision-making if they possess more private information themselves (Chen et al., 2007).
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Manager | Analyst | Institutional investors | All additional controls | |
AIA*Q | 0.0225** | 0.0236** | 0.0247** | 0.0216* |
(0.04) | (0.04) | (0.03) | (0.06) | |
SUE*Q | −0.0273 | −0.0286 | ||
(0.18) | (0.18) | |||
Analyst*Q | −0.0041 | 0.0010 | ||
(0.81) | (0.95) | |||
Ins*Q | 0.0225** | 0.0236** | 0.0247** | 0.0216* |
(0.04) | (0.04) | (0.03) | (0.06) | |
Controls & lower order terms | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 24,080 | 24,463 | 24,463 | 24,080 |
R 2 | 0.6721 | 0.6699 | 0.6670 | 0.6722 |
- Note: This table further controls the impact of information sources and institutional investors on the association between AIA and investment efficiency. Column (1) shows the impact of abnormal institutional attention on investment-Q sensitivity (AIA*Q) controlling the impact of managerial information (SUE*Q). Column (2) shows the impact of abnormal institutional attention on investment-Q sensitivity (AIA*Q) controlling the impact of analysts' information (Analyst*Q). Column (3) shows the impact of abnormal institutional attention on investment-Q sensitivity (AIA*Q) controlling institutional investors (Ins*Q). Column (4) includes all the additional controls in the control set. Year-Quarter fixed effects and firm fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All other variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
I measure analysts' information using analyst coverage level (Analyst). Column (2) of Table 9 reports the regression controlling analysts' information. I continue to find a positive and significant coefficient of AIA*Q. The negative coefficient of Analyst*Q is consistent with the argument that analysts mainly transfer information from managers to markets instead of producing new information themselves (Agrawal et al., 2006). Therefore, while analysts can help incorporate managerial information into the stock price, such information is unlikely to affect the investment decisions of managers. As a result, a negative relationship between analysts and investment-Q sensitivity is expected.
5.4.2 Controlling for institutional ownership
Another alternative explanation could be that firms with a greater portion of institutional investors have better investment efficiency. Such firms also receive more AIA on the earnings announcement day. To rule out this possibility, I further control for institutional investor ownership (Ins*Q). As reported in column (3) of Table 9, I find that the coefficient of AIA*Q is still positive and significant at the 5% level after controlling for institutional investor ownership, whereas the coefficient of Ins*Q is insignificant. This result suggests that the relationship between institutional investor attention and investment efficiency is not driven by institutional ownership.
In column (4) of Table 9, I report the regression controlling private managerial information, analysts' information and institutional ownership. I find the result remains unchanged. Overall, the results in this section provide further support for the argument that AIA encourages institutional investors to incorporate more private information into the stock price, allowing managers to invest more efficiently by learning from such information.
5.4.3 Controlling for the information content of the announcement
It could be argued that a higher Bloomberg search volume is driven by a higher level of new information released by this firm. Therefore, the manager would like to learn more from the market as there is a higher level of uncertainty about the firm's future investment opportunity. To rule out this alternative explanation, I further control for the level of information released in the earnings announcement period.
To do so, I employ the following two proxies to capture the information level. The first proxy is AVOL (abnormal trading volume), which measures the abnormal trading volume during the 3-day window around the firm's earnings announcement (days −1 to 1), scaled by the average trading volume during the current quarter, excluding the earnings announcement period. As a substantial influx of new information tends to trigger abnormally greater trading in the market (Bajo, 2010), the abnormal trading volume can be used as a proxy for the level of information released during this period. The second proxy is AVAR (abnormal stock return variance), which is an alternative measure of information content. It captures the abnormal stock return variance during the 3-day earnings announcement window (average stock return variance during the 3 days around the firm's earnings announcement, scaled by the average stock return variance during the current quarter, excluding the earnings announcement period). Higher abnormal return variance around the announcement day suggests greater uncertainty faced by managers regarding the firm's future investment opportunities, implying that more information has been released during the earnings announcement period.
Appendix 3 reports the results of additional control for information content released during the earnings announcement period. Column (1) reports the results using AVOL as the proxy for information content, and column (2) reports the results using AVAR as the proxy. The findings show that institutional attention continues to have a positive effect on investment efficiency, even after considering variations in information content during the earnings announcement days. These results suggest that the main findings are less likely to be driven by the level of information released by firms.
5.4.4 Controlling for the salience of the news around the earnings announcement
In addition, salience, which plays a crucial role in determining the attention-grabbing nature of information (Huang et al., 2018), may also affect investors' effort in monitoring a firm, which could consequently influence the investment efficiency of the firm. To disentangle the effect of institutional attention from the salience of news around the earnings announcement, I follow the approach of Huang et al. (2018). Specifically, salience is quantified using the average number of quantitative items in a firm's press release headlines on the earnings announcement day, obtained from RavenPack.
With the salience measure, I conduct two tests to rule out the alternative explanation that the findings are attributed to the salience of news around the earnings announcement rather than institutional attention. First, in column (1) of Appendix 4, I further include salience as an additional control in the baseline regression; second, in column (2) of Appendix 4, I report the result using an alternative measure of AIA (i.e., AIARES), which disentangles the effect of salience from the current AIA measure. Specifically, the second test involved regressing AIA on Salience and recording the residual as AIARES, which captures institutional attention not related to salience. Subsequently, the baseline regression was rerun, replacing AIA with AIARES. If the impact of AIA on investment efficiency is purely attributable to salience, AIARES should not affect investment efficiency.
The results reported in Appendix 4 indicate that even after accounting for salience, AIA continues to significantly impact investment efficiency. These findings suggest that salience is less likely to be the primary factor contributing to the impact of AIA on investment efficiency.
5.5 Alternative measures
To ensure that my findings are not subject to measurement error, I rerun the baseline regression using alternative measures of abnormal institutional attention. Specifically, I follow Loughran and McDonald (2014) and measure abnormal institutional attention (AEDGAR) as the natural logarithm of the ratio of EDGAR on day t to EDGAR over the previous month. EDGAR refers to the daily number of unique requests for firm filings in the SEC EDGAR server. I obtain the data of the EDGAR filing request of 2011–2015 from the website provided by Loughran and McDonald (2017),7 and manually collect the request of 2016–2017 from the US Securities and Exchange Commission website.8 To better interpret the extent to which abnormal attention impacts investment-Q sensitivity, I first generate two dummy abnormal attention measures based on AEDGAR: (1) AEDGAR_P, a dummy variable that is equal to one if AEDGAR is a positive figure and zero otherwise – a positive AEDGAR suggests that firms received more filing download requests on day t compared to the previous month; (2) AEDGAR_MED, a dummy variable that is equal to one if a firm's AEDGAR is above the sample median and zero otherwise. After constructing the two dummy variables as alternative measures of abnormal institutional attention, I interact each of them with Q and rerun the baseline regression.
Additionally, as investment decisions may not be limited to specific days, such as earnings announcement days, I have repeated the baseline regression utilising a quarterly measure of institutional attention, denoted as AIAQTR. AIAQTR is a dummy variable taking the value of one when the quarterly median of the Bloomberg attention score for a firm falls within the range of 3 or 4, signifying abnormally high attention. In contrast, it is assigned a value of zero otherwise. Unlike the previous measure (i.e., AIA), which focused exclusively on the earnings announcement day, AIAQTR relies on the Bloomberg score for a given firm across the entire quarter. This broader scope accounts for institutional attention received by the firm throughout the quarter, which can mitigate the concern that investment decisions can be made at any time, not necessarily around earnings announcements.
Table 10 reports the results. I find that the results are consistent with the findings of the baseline regression, indicating that the findings are robust to these alternative proxies for abnormal institutional attention.
(1) | (2) | (3) | |
---|---|---|---|
Dependent variable: Inv | |||
AEDGAR_P | AEDGAR_MED | AIAQTR | |
AIA*Q | 0.0182* | 0.0178* | 0.0433** |
(0.08) | (0.08) | (2.06) | |
AIA | −0.0389 | −0.0352 | −0.1008 |
(0.14) | (0.16) | (−1.30) | |
Q | 0.0300* | 0.0308* | 0.0399** |
(0.06) | (0.06) | (2.64) | |
CF | 1.5404*** | 1.5396*** | 1.5291*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (4.42) | |
Leverage | −0.0050*** | −0.0050*** | −0.0050*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (−4.24) | |
Asset1 | 11.4303 | 11.4563 | 11.0649 |
(0.14) | (0.13) | (1.48) | |
MrtCap | 0.2343*** | 0.2343*** | 0.2368*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (5.27) | |
Age | −0.0022 | −0.0022 | 0.0796 |
(0.38) | (0.39) | (0.83) | |
LnNumEst | 0.0748 | 0.0747 | −0.0021 |
(0.40) | (0.40) | (−0.78) | |
Inst | −0.0311 | −0.0306 | −0.0292 |
(0.82) | (0.83) | (−0.21) | |
SUE | −0.1019 | −0.1023 | −0.0984 |
(0.55) | (0.55) | (−0.59) | |
_cons | −0.7275* | −0.7320* | −0.7844 |
(0.09) | (0.09) | (−1.67) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes | Yes |
N | 24,463 | 24,463 | 24,463 |
R 2 | 0.6696 | 0.6696 | 0.6845 |
- Note: This table presents the relationship between abnormal institutional attention and investment-Q sensitivity, using an alternative measurement of abnormal institutional attention. The dependent variable is investment (i.e., capital expenditure). Column (1) reports the result using AEDGAR_P as the alternative measurement. Column (2) reports the result using AEDGAR_MED as the alternative measurement. Column (3) reports the result using AIAQTR as the alternative measurement. Firm fixed and year-quarter firm fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
The residual of the above regression (InvInef) captures the deviation of current firm investment from its optimal level and thus measures the investment inefficiency of a firm. The negative coefficient associated with AIA in Appendix 5 indicates that higher levels of AIA can alleviate this investment inefficiency, consistently highlighting the positive influence of institutional attention on investment efficiency.
6 CONCLUSION
In this paper, I examined the effect of AIA on investment efficiency. I find that firms receiving abnormal institutional attention on the earnings announcement day invest more efficiently in the following quarter. This finding is robust to additional control variables, endogeneity tests and alternative measurements of attention. Moreover, I find a positive association between AIA and price informativeness, and I find that the impact of AIA on investment efficiency is stronger when institutional investors have greater incentives to incorporate their own information and when corporate managers have greater incentives or are more capable of using the incremental information contained in the stock price. These findings are consistent with the managerial learning hypothesis by showing that AIA encourages institutional investors to incorporate more information into stock prices, guiding managers to invest efficiently.
The findings in this paper have implications for several strands of finance research. First, this study answers the call from Baker and Wurgler (2013) and provides empirical evidence showing that limited attention can influence corporate decisions. Specifically, the results indicate that abnormal institutional attention strongly impacts corporate investment decisions. Second, this research also has implications for the literature on asset pricing. The finding that attention from sophisticated investors (i.e., institutional investors) is associated with price informativeness suggests that asset-pricing models should integrate attention and assign a significant role to it. Third, this research adds to the debate about whether price efficiency can improve real efficiency. By showing that institutional attention, an essential factor that influences price informativeness, is associated with investment efficiency, this study additionally supports this strand of literature.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I thank Yushu (Elizabeth) Zhu, Barry Oliver, Khoa Hoang and Lei Zhang for their valuable comments on the earlier version of this paper. Open access publishing facilitated by The University of Queensland, as part of the Wiley - The University of Queensland agreement via the Council of Australian University Librarians.
APPENDIX 1: VARIABLES DEFINITION
Independent variables | |
---|---|
Bloomberg records the number of times news articles on a particular stock are read by its terminal users and the number of times users actively search for news for a specific stock. Bloomberg then assigns a value of one for each article read and 10 for each news search. These numbers are then aggregated into an hourly count. Using the hourly count, Bloomberg then creates a numerical attention score each hour by comparing the past 8-h average count to all hourly counts over the previous month for the same stock. They assign a value of zero if the rolling average is in the lowest 80% of the hourly counts over the previous 30 days. Similarly, Bloomberg assigns a score of 1, 2, 3 or 4 if the average is between 80% and 90%, 90% and 94%, 94% and 96%, or greater than 96% of the previous 30 days' hourly counts, respectively. Finally, Bloomberg aggregates up to the daily frequency by taking a maximum of all hourly scores throughout the day. These are the data provided to us by Bloomberg. Since I am interested in abnormal attention, the AIA measure is a dummy variable that receives a value of one if Bloomberg's score is 3 or 4 and zero otherwise. This captures the right tail of the measure's distribution | |
An alternative measure for AIA. AEDGAR_P is a dummy variable that is equal to one if AEDGAR is a positive figure, and zero otherwise. AEDGAR is the natural logarithm of the ratio of EDGAR on day t to the EDGAR over the previous month. EDGAR refers to the daily number of unique requests for firm filings on the SEC EDGAR server. I obtain the data for EDGAR filing requests from the website provided by Loughran and McDonald (2017) | |
An alternative measure for AIA. AEDGAR_MED is a dummy variable that is equal to one if AEDGAR is above median average, and zero otherwise | |
The ratio of market value of assets to book value of assets at the quarterly frequency, following Chen et al. (2007); Q = (mv1 + atq – ceqq)/atq, where mvq is the market value (shares outstanding * stock price at the end of the quarter), and ceqq is the book value of equity |
Dependent variables | |
---|---|
Capital expenditure at the quarterly frequency, scaled by beginning-of-quarter total assets (%), following Chen et al. (2007) |
Other variables | |
---|---|
Price nonsynchronicity measure, where R2 is estimated following Chen et al. (2007) and Ferreira et al. (2011) | |
Cash flow at the quarterly frequency, computed as income before extraordinary items + depreciation and amortisation, scaled by lagged total assets | |
Leverage at the quarterly frequency, the ratio of book value of debt to book value of assets | |
Firm age in years, defined as current year minus the IPO year/the first year that the firm appears on the CRSP database | |
1 divided by the book value of the beginning-of-quarter total assets, following Chen et al. (2007). This variable is included to isolate the correlation between Inv and Q induced by the common scaling variable (i.e., the beginning-of-quarter total assets) | |
The natural logarithm of the number of analysts covering the stock using the most recent information | |
The natural logarithm of total market capital | |
An indicator that takes the value of one if a firm's institutional ownership for a given quarter is greater than the average level and zero otherwise | |
Managerial private information, calculated based on earnings surprise. Earnings surprise is computed as the abnormal stock return around the earnings announcement dates | |
An indicator that takes the value of one if a firm's WW index for a given quarter is greater than the average level and zero otherwise | |
An indicator that takes the value of one if a firm's market capital for a given quarter is greater than the average level and zero otherwise | |
An indicator that takes the value of one if a firm's three-digit HHI index for a given quarter is greater than the average level and zero otherwise | |
An indicator that takes the value of one if a firm's analyst coverage for a given quarter is greater than the average level and zero otherwise | |
An indicator that takes the value of one if a firm's positive news accounts for more than 50% of the total news over a 90-day window and zero otherwise | |
EAIA | The median AIA across the previous four earnings announcements |
NoAnnouncement | The total number of earning announcements by firms other than the focal firm on the firm's earning announcement date |
APPENDIX 2: PSM BALANCE TEST
Dependent variable: AIA | ||
---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | |
Pre-match sample | Post-match sample | |
Q | 0.0055 | 0.0025 |
(0.14) | (0.68) | |
CF | −0.3961*** | 0.0146 |
(0.00) | (0.94) | |
Leverage | 0.0028*** | −0.0003 |
(0.00) | (0.56) | |
Asset1 | −5.7840*** | −2.9760 |
(0.00) | (0.30) | |
MrtCap | 0.1433*** | −0.0071 |
(0.00) | (0.46) | |
Age | −0.0028*** | −0.0000 |
(0.00) | (0.96) | |
LnNumEst | −0.0023 | 0.0020 |
(0.86) | (0.91) | |
Inst | −0.0104 | −0.0104 |
(0.74) | (0.82) | |
SUE | −0.0197 | −0.0594 |
(0.80) | (0.61) | |
_cons | −0.4697*** | 0.5662*** |
(0.00) | (0.00) | |
N | 24,463 | 9976 |
R 2 | 0.3044 | −0.0003 |
- Note: This table reports the pre-match and post-match samples of the PSM analysis. Firm fixed and year-quarter fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
APPENDIX 3: FURTHER CONTROL FOR THE INFORMATION CONTENT OF ANNOUNCEMENTS
(1) | (2) | |
---|---|---|
Dependent variable: Inv | ||
AIA*Q | 0.0217** | 0.0218** |
(2.07) | (2.08) | |
AIA | −0.0858*** | −0.0862*** |
(−2.72) | (−2.73) | |
Q | 0.0376*** | 0.0376*** |
(2.65) | (2.65) | |
CF | 1.5652*** | 1.5673*** |
(4.17) | (4.18) | |
Leverage | −0.0043*** | −0.0043*** |
(−3.37) | (−3.37) | |
Asset1 | 1.4880 | 1.5043 |
(0.20) | (0.20) | |
MrtCap | 0.2349*** | 0.2349*** |
(4.73) | (4.73) | |
Age | −0.0314 | −0.0319 |
(−0.32) | (−0.33) | |
LnNumEst | −0.0024 | −0.0024 |
(−1.26) | (−1.26) | |
Inst | 0.0080 | 0.0085 |
(0.04) | (0.05) | |
SUE | 0.0566 | 0.0561 |
(0.37) | (0.37) | |
AVAR | 0.0004 | |
(0.11) | ||
AVOL | −0.0116 | |
(−0.81) | ||
_cons | −0.4966 | −0.4946 |
(−1.02) | (−1.01) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes |
N | 18,521 | 18,521 |
R 2 | 0.6873 | 0.6873 |
- Note: This table reports the result controlling the information content of announcements. Column (1) reports the results using AVOL as the proxy for information content, where AVOL measures the abnormal trading volume during the 3-day window around the firm's earnings announcement (days −1 to 1), scaled by the average trading volume during the current quarter, excluding the earnings announcement period. Column (2) reports the results using AVAR as the proxy, where AVAR captures the abnormal stock return variance during the 3-day earnings announcement window (average stock return variance during the 3 days around the firm's earnings announcement, scaled by the average stock return variance during the current quarter, excluding the earnings announcement period). Firm fixed and year-quarter fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
APPENDIX 4: FURTHER CONTROL FOR THE SALIENCE OF ANNOUNCEMENTS
(1) | (2) | |
---|---|---|
Dependent variable: Inv | ||
AIA*Q | 0.0272** | |
(2.23) | ||
AIARES*Q | 0.0271** | |
(2.28) | ||
AIA | −0.1016*** | |
(−3.16) | ||
AIARES | −0.0957*** | |
(−3.14) | ||
Q | 0.0282 | 0.0438*** |
(1.55) | (2.77) | |
CF | 1.5203*** | 1.5278*** |
(3.94) | (3.96) | |
Leverage | −0.0058*** | −0.0058*** |
(−4.95) | (−4.98) | |
Asset1 | 10.2170 | 10.1366 |
(0.93) | (0.92) | |
MrtCap | 0.2410*** | 0.2397*** |
(5.17) | (5.15) | |
Age | −0.0019 | −0.0018 |
(−0.81) | (−0.77) | |
LnNumEst | 0.0687 | 0.0693 |
(0.77) | (0.78) | |
Inst | −0.0543 | −0.0529 |
(−0.36) | (−0.35) | |
SUE | −0.1467 | −0.1521 |
(−0.76) | (−0.79) | |
Salience | 0.0263 | |
(0.85) | ||
_cons | −0.7248 | −0.7430* |
(−1.63) | (−1.69) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes | Yes |
Firm | Yes | Yes |
N | 20,973 | 20,973 |
R 2 | 0.7029 | 0.7028 |
- Note: This table reports the result controlling the salience of announcements. Column (1) reports the result further controlling the salience of announcements, where the salience is estimated as the average number of quantitative items in a firm's press release headlines on the earnings announcement day following Huang et al. (2018). Column (2) reports the results using AIARES as the alternative measure of institutional attention. AIARES is the residual of regressing AIA on Salience, and thus captures institutional attention not related to salience. Firm fixed and year-quarter fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
APPENDIX 5: ALTERNATIVE MEASURE OF INVESTMENT EFFICIENCY
Dependent variable: InvInef | |
---|---|
AIA | −0.0010** |
(−1.97) | |
Q | −0.0004** |
(−2.07) | |
CF | 0.0120* |
(1.94) | |
Leverage | 0.0000 |
(0.64) | |
Asset1 | 0.2233* |
(1.91) | |
MrtCap | 0.0008 |
(1.52) | |
Age | 0.0002*** |
(3.16) | |
LnNumEst | −0.0048 |
(−1.33) | |
Inst | 0.0051** |
(1.97) | |
SUE | 0.0059 |
(1.49) | |
_cons | 0.0115 |
(1.12) | |
Year-Quarter | Yes |
Firm | Yes |
N | 22,075 |
R 2 | 0.1505 |
- Note: This table reports the result with an alternative measure of investment efficiency following Richardson (2006), where the dependent variable InvInef captures the deviation of current firm investment from its optimal level. Firm fixed and year-quarter fixed effects are controlled. Robust standard errors, clustered by firm and year, are in parentheses, *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% two-tailed levels, respectively. All variables are as defined in Appendix 1.
- Bold values are for indicating variables of interest. The significant level are inidcated using the stars.
Open Research
DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT
The data that support the findings of this study are available on request from the corresponding author.
REFERENCES
- 1 Institutional equity ownership has risen dramatically in the past 30 years to the extent that institutional investors owned more than 65% of US common equity by the 2010s (Borochin & Yang, 2017). Given this dominant role, institutional investors have a great influence on the financial market and corporate decisions (Ben-Rephael et al., 2017).
- 2 There is a growing literature on how institutional distraction affects corporate policies (Garel et al., 2021; Kempf et al., 2017; Liu et al., 2020; Schmidt, 2019).
- 3 Abnormal institutional attention refers to when institutional investors spend significantly more time in searching and reading the news about a firm on Bloomberg terminals.
- 4 .
- 5 This data is obtained from Ravenpack (AES).
- 6 For example, when a firm (Firm A) does not belong to an industry with extreme returns (Industry A), institutional investors' attention may be distracted by unrelated industries experiencing extreme returns (Industry B and Industry C). Given that the industry returns of unrelated industries (Industry B and Industry C) are exogenous to the characteristics of Firm A, they can be regarded as exogenous negative shocks to the institutional attention received by a firm.
- 7 The data is available at https://sraf.nd.edu/data/.
- 8 The data is available at https://www.sec.gov/dera/data/edgar-log-file-data-set.html.