Volume 41, Issue 1 pp. 46-71
RESEARCH ARTICLE
Full Access

Forecasting equity returns: The role of commodity futures along the supply chain

Chenchen Li

Chenchen Li

Department of Finance, Antai College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai, China

Search for more papers by this author
Chongfeng Wu

Chongfeng Wu

Department of Finance, Antai College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai, China

Search for more papers by this author
Chunyang Zhou

Corresponding Author

Chunyang Zhou

Department of Finance, Antai College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai, China

Correspondence Chunyang Zhou, Department of Finance, Antai College of Economics and Management, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, 200030 Shanghai, China.

Email: [email protected]

Search for more papers by this author
First published: 17 October 2020
Citations: 2

Abstract

This paper examines equity return predictability using the returns of commodity futures along the supply chain in China's financial market. We find that a considerable number of commodities exhibit significant in-sample forecasting ability at the daily horizon, especially for supplier-side equity returns. The macroeconomic risk premium effect, captured by the aggregate commodity prices, is an important source for this predictability. The out-of-sample results show that for most commodities, the predictability remains both statistically and economically significant, and the forecasting performance improves substantially during recessions or with economic constraints.

1 INTRODUCTION

As is well documented in previous studies (e.g., Grossman, 1977; Hong & Yogo, 2012), futures prices are informative about prospective economic activity and asset prices. Hence, in recent years, there has been a growing trend to study the relationship between commodity futures returns and stock returns. Our study, however, examines this relationship from a new perspective: the cross-market supply-chain linkage in China's market. China is a leading producer and consumer of many commodities, but less-studied than other markets. Utilizing a novel data set provided by the Wind company, which identifies the supplier-side and customer-side stocks for each commodity, we build this cross-market supply-chain relationship between commodity futures and equities. Our paper potentially enriches two main strands of literature, specifically, the cross-market asset return linkage and the supply-chain equity return predictability.

The main purpose of this paper is to examine whether commodity futures returns have significant ability to predict the supplier-side and customer-side stock returns. There are several possible factors that may contribute to such predictability. First, the price information from commodity futures may impact the supply-chain linked firms through expected macroeconomic activity. Barsky and Kilian (2004) document that commodity prices are informative with respect to macroeconomic fundamentals and the related macroeconomic variables (e.g., dividend-price ratio, dividend yield, earning-price ratio, inflation, etc.) are prevailing predictors for equity risk premiums (Goyal & Welch, 2008). Second, the equity investors will underreact to a firm's new information due to their limited processing capacity (Kandel & Pearson, 1995) or precious cognitive resources (Nisbett & Ross, 1983), and thus, there is stock return predictability in the short term. This notion is theoretically explained by the limited information model (e.g., Hong & Stein, 1999; Merton, 1987; L. Peng & Xiong, 2006) and empirically supported by a large battery of literature (e.g., Cohen, Frazzini, & Malloy, 2008; Hou, 2007; Lo & MacKinlay, 1990). Third, the cross-market trading activity has substantially increased in the past decades. Büyükşahin and Robe (2014) find that the correlation between the returns on investible commodities and equity indices increases with greater speculation participation.

In our paper, we first construct supplier-side and customer-side equity portfolios for each commodity and implement the in-sample predictive exercise for equity portfolio returns using lagged commodity futures returns at the daily horizon from 2005 to 2019. Using the standard univariate regression, we find that a notable number of commodities, specifically, 27 out of 36 commodity futures on the supplier side and 16 out of 36 commodity futures on the customer side, exhibit significant in-sample forecasting abilities. Continuing to use the multivariate regression to control common pricing factors, including the market risk factor, size risk factor and growth risk factor, we find that although the significance of such predictability is partially subsumed, it still remains, especially for supplier-side equities. To shed light on the economic channels of this predictability, we use the principle component of all the commodity futures returns to proxy an overall macroeconomic risk premium effect and identify it as an important source of the predictability. Besides the test for each individual commodity, the pooled regression across all the commodities further shows that the predictability is significant as well on average.

Next, we examine the out-of-sample forecasting performance of this cross-market supply-chain predictor. Using the recursive prediction strategy, the out-of-sample significance still exists, albeit it is weaker than the in-sample performance. The commodity futures, such as those for iron ore, glass, methanol, coking coal, and corn, obtain significant out-of-sample performance for both the supplier and customer sides. Based on the results of the out-of-sample portfolio allocation, we further confirm the economic gains for our predictive model relative to the stringent benchmark model using historical average returns. In addition, the out-of-sample tests show that this equity return predictability is still more prominent for the supplier-side portfolios.

Finally, we extend our analysis by considering the business cycle and economic constraints, and find that the cross-market supply-chain predictability is stronger in recessionary periods during which the investors are more risk averse. When imposing the economic constraints of the equity premium and Sharpe ratio, the out-of-sample forecasting performance significantly improves.

A number of studies examine the return linkage between commodity future and equities, and most of them focus on one particular commodity category. Although Büyüksahin et al. (2009) document that the lack of greater return comovement across the U.S. equities and commodities challenges the hypothesis that commodities gradually move in synchronization with equity assets, more recent studies provide abundant evidence to support such a linkage (e.g., Bouri et al., 2017; Jacobsen et al., 2019; Kang et al., 2015; S. F. Li et al., 2012; Narayan & Sharma, 2011; C. Peng et al., 2018; Wang et al., 2019; Wong & Zhang, 2020). Due to the great demand for energy and metals over the past decades, these commodities play a more critical role than other commodities when determining prospective equity returns. Narayan and Sharma (2011) and Wang et al. (2019) find that oil prices can predict the returns of individual stock and the S&P 500 index in the U.S. stock market. C. Peng et al. (2018) examine the risk spillover from international crude oil market to stock market while Wong and Zhang (2020) document that the shocks of crude oil futures have a significant influence on the returns of several industries in China's stock market. Additionally, Hu and Xiong (2013) find that the overnight returns of copper and soybeans futures traded in the United States have significantly positive predictive powers for stock price movements in major East Asian economies. Jacobsen et al. (2019) also find that the price movements in industrial metals such as copper and aluminum can predict stock returns. Compared with previous studies, our paper is more fundamentally oriented and builds a comprehensive framework that links multiple commodities with the related equities using the supply-chain relationship.

The existing evidence of supply-chain return predictability has well covered the stock markets. Although Agarwal and Chua (2020) document that financial information is currently more salient with lower search costs, the supply-chain information still diffuses slowly. For instance, Menzly and Ozbas (2006), Cohen and Frazzini (2008), Menzly and Ozbas (2010), and Herskovic (2018) provide empirical evidence in the U.S. market, while Shahrur et al. (2010) document consistent results in other developed markets. C. Li et al. (2020) also find the supply-chain predictability in China's stock market. The key finding of these studies is that stock returns can be cross-sectionally predicted by either the supplier-side or customer-side portfolio returns. In addition, such equity predictability cannot be easily absorbed through traditional asset-pricing determinants. In this paper, we address the limitation of the previous literature by combining the economic intuition of supply-chain predictability with the informativeness of commodity futures. Our study answers the question whether the economic linkage along the supply chain can explain the security return variation not only within a stock market but also across different markets. This may fill the gap in the literature that, to the best of our knowledge, has not been examined in previous studies.

The rest of our paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data. Section 3 presents the in-sample tests. Section 4 reports the out-of-sample forecasting results. Section 5 extend the analysis in Section 4 by examining the forecasting model during different business cycles or under economic constraints. Finally, Section 6 concludes.

2 DATA DESCRIPTION

2.1 Data source

The purpose of this paper is to examine the cross-market supply-chain predictability in China's financial market, which is the world's largest commodity futures market and the world's second-largest equity market. Based on the 2018 world ranking of commodity derivative trading volumes reported by the Futures Industry Association (FIA), Shanghai Futures Exchange (SHFE), Dalian Commodity Exchange (DCE) and Zhengzhou Commodity Exchange (ZCE) in mainland China occupy three of the top four positions. Not surprisingly, the pricing content contained in the commodity futures should be quite informative because of the huge trading volumes.

We collect the historical prices of the commodity futures and stocks in Mainland China from the CSMAR, covering the period from January 4, 2005 to December 31, 2019. To identify suppliers and customers in the stock market for each commodity, we use a novel data set from the Wind company, which provides this cross-market supply-chain linkage.

We select the commodity futures based on the following steps. First, we collect 60 commodity futures traded in China's future market during the period from year 2005 to 2019. Second, to have enough observations for the in-sample and out-of-sample tests, we delete 11 recently listed commodity futures whose numbers of trading days are less than 500 (soda ash, styrene, stainless steel, japonica rice RR, No. 20 rubber, urea, nonbleached kraft pulp, jujube, glycol, crude oil, and apple). Third, we continue to delete three commodities (ferrosilicon, mung bean, and late indica rice) because these commodities do not simultaneously link with both supplier-side and customer-side firms. Finally, we delete 10 commodities (blockboard, fiberboard, wire rod, fuel oil, rapeseed, wheat PM, wheat WT, japonica rice JR, early indica rice, and cotton yarn) which have very low trading volumes and produce discontinuous futures returns. In this way, we have 36 commodity futures for our analysis, belonging to four categories, that is, metals, industrials, energy, and agriculture. Specifically, the commodity futures traded on the SHFE, DCE, and ZCE are categorized into the following groups: (a) metals: silver, aluminum, gold, copper, iron ore, nickel, lead, steel rebar, silicon manganese, tin, and zinc; (b) industrials: glass, hot rolled coil, linear low-density polyethylene (LLDPE), methanol, polypropylene (PP), natural rubber, pure terephthalic acid (PTA), and polyvinyl chloride (PVC) (c) energy: bitumen, coke, coking coal, and thermal coal; and (d) agriculture: No. 1 soybeans, No. 2 soybeans, corn, cotton, corn starch, eggs, soybean meal, rapeseed oil, palm oil, rapeseed meal, white sugar, wheat WH, and soybean oil.

2.2 Summary statistics

Based on the supply-chain linkage information from the Wind data set, we build the supplier-side and customer-side stock portfolios for each commodity in China's financial market. We calculate the value-weighted equity returns at the daily horizon, excluding the newly listed stocks within 1 month.

To construct the continuous series of commodity futures returns, the common methodology is to use the nearest-to-maturity contracts (Booth et al., 1999) or on-the-run contracts (Fricke & Menkhoff, 2011), which are the futures contracts that have the largest trading volume during the specific trading period. In this paper, we obtain the time-series on-the-run contracts for each commodity at the daily horizon because this selection avoids the low liquidity problem of nearest-to-maturity contracts in China's commodity futures market. We obtain on-the-run futures returns for each commodity as follows. First, we select the future contract with the largest trading volume at trading day t. Next, we obtain the close prices for the future contract at day t and t − 1, and then calculate the daily return at day t using these close prices. We repeat this process for each trading day and obtain the time-series returns of on-the-run future.

We first present the overview of each commodity future and the numbers of supplier-side and customer-side listed firms in Table 1. The futures category, futures name, futures code, number of trading days, average daily trading volume, on-the-run contract observations, and average maturities are reported for each commodity futures. The number of trading days for the commodity futures varies from 1,165 to 3,648 during the full sample period as some of them are not listed at the beginning. Additionally, the detailed lists of the supplier-side and customer-side equities for each commodity, which are omitted for brevity, are available in the Wind data set.

Table 1. Data description of commodity futures and the cross-market supply-chain linkage
No. Futures category Futures name Futures code Trading days Avg. trading volume Rolling contract obs. Avg. maturity Supplier firm obs. Customer firm obs.
1 Metals Silver AG 1,864 920,009 18 121.02 9 3
2 Metals Aluminum AL 3,648 173,618 180 73.66 18 306
3 Metals Gold AU 2,916 143,808 26 136.33 26 9
4 Metals Copper CU 3,648 400,482 180 74.34 17 110
5 Metals Iron ore I 1,517 2,059,113 19 114.23 8 43
6 Metals Nickel NI 1,165 881,129 23 88.29 6 9
7 Metals Lead PB 2,137 35,832 102 52.97 12 241
8 Metals Steel rebar RB 2,621 3,452,723 37 136.19 52 416
9 Metals Silicon manganese SM 1,317 86,144 27 81.26 14 27
10 Metals Tin SN 1,165 20,181 18 79.49 2 3
11 Metals Zinc ZN 3,111 458,400 152 72.98 9 277
12 Industrials Glass FG 1,723 565,660 22 110.76 47 476
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil HC 1,413 434,408 18 109.06 59 389
14 Industrials LLDPE L 3,025 538,248 42 110.64 113 11
15 Industrials Methanol MA 1,991 1,054,471 26 100.65 127 34
16 Industrials PP PP 1,428 638,166 19 102.03 114 323
17 Industrials Natural rubber RU 3,648 606,689 72 113.25 1 280
18 Industrials PTA TA 3,173 1,009,026 41 106.25 74 102
19 Industrials PVC V 2,582 130,191 35 109.09 113 259
20 Energy Bitumen BU 1,524 647,176 21 100.33 10 46
21 Energy Coke J 2,123 418,588 27 111.78 75 35
22 Energy Coking coal JM 1,652 314,947 21 108.68 75 35
23 Energy Thermal coal ZC 1,528 222,556 21 91.48 65 260
24 Agriculture No. 1 soybean A 3,648 283,486 47 166.49 11 46
25 Agriculture No. 2 soybean B 3,648 24,588 89 164.41 11 46
26 Agriculture Corn C 3,648 442,147 53 170.38 15 43
27 Agriculture Cotton CF 3,648 311,312 47 140.56 9 97
28 Agriculture Corn starch CS 1,228 299,932 16 102.95 15 43
29 Agriculture Egg JD 1,502 224,298 19 157.6 5 23
30 Agriculture Soybean meal M 3,648 1,476,588 49 137.99 36 46
31 Agriculture Rapeseed oil OI 3,062 129,800 41 149.22 6 5
32 Agriculture Palm oil P 2,966 552,097 40 125.26 4 3
33 Agriculture Rapeseed meal RM 1,704 1,518,751 22 113.28 4 49
34 Agriculture White sugar SR 3,404 985,836 33 162.72 21 120
35 Agriculture Wheat WH WH 3,648 81,983 50 148.65 5 79
36 Agriculture Soybean oil Y 3,403 545,170 43 153.42 7 4
Avg. 2,502 613,543 47 116.60 33 119
  • Note: This table reports the data description of commodity futures and the related supply-chain linkage. The details of futures category, futures name, futures code, trading days, average daily trading volume, on-the-run contract observations, and average maturities are individually presented for each commodity. The last two columns of this table show the numbers of supplier-side and customer-side listed firms for each commodity. The full sample period covers Jan 2005–Dec 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period.

Table 2 reports the summary statistics of the futures returns and the related supplier-side and customer-side equity portfolio returns. For each commodity futures, we present the mean, standard deviation and first-order autocorrelation of the time-series returns. The first-order autocorrelation coefficients of the supplier-side (or customer-side) stock returns are always positive, indicating positive momentum at the daily horizon in China's stock market. In the last three columns of Table 2, the correlation among the three returns series are also presented. We find that all the correlation coefficients between commodity futures returns and supplier-side (customer-side) stock returns are positive with an average value of 0.21 (0.18), indicating that there exists cross-market return comovement along the supply chain.

Table 2. Summary statistics for commodity futures returns and equity portfolio returns
Commodity futures return (%) Supplier equity portfolio return (%) Customer equity portfolio return (%) Correlation
No. Futures category Futures name Mean SD AR1 Mean SD AR1 Mean SD AR1 ( R _ com, R _ sup ) ( R _ com R _ cust ) ( R _ sup, R_cust )
1 Metals Silver −0.02 1.32 −0.01 0.02 2.24 0.05 0.05 2.17 0.03 0.29 0.28 0.62
2 Metals Aluminum 0.00 1.02 −0.06 0.06 2.65 0.06 0.08 2.02 0.06 0.32 0.23 0.82
3 Metals Gold 0.02 1.11 −0.04 0.00 2.30 0.05 0.00 2.30 0.06 0.31 0.22 0.86
4 Metals Copper 0.04 1.54 −0.04 0.07 2.76 0.04 0.09 2.02 0.06 0.43 0.24 0.74
5 Metals Iron ore 0.06 2.10 0.06 0.03 2.38 0.14 0.05 2.11 0.04 0.19 0.24 0.72
6 Metals Nickel 0.02 1.60 0.05 0.03 2.75 0.08 -0.02 2.49 0.08 0.26 0.26 0.77
7 Metals Lead 0.00 1.14 −0.05 0.00 2.31 0.07 0.01 1.67 0.05 0.29 0.20 0.83
8 Metals Steel rebar 0.01 1.41 0.00 0.01 2.01 0.04 0.03 1.73 0.05 0.32 0.22 0.86
9 Metals Silicon manganese 0.06 1.63 0.00 0.03 2.46 0.03 0.04 2.20 0.03 0.15 0.14 0.88
10 Metals Tin 0.00 1.10 0.02 0.01 2.78 0.00 -0.01 2.75 0.02 0.27 0.29 0.89
11 Metals Zinc −0.01 1.55 −0.03 0.04 2.85 0.08 0.04 2.08 0.07 0.41 0.29 0.79
12 Industrials Glass 0.04 1.27 −0.06 0.05 1.92 0.08 0.06 1.78 0.08 0.14 0.15 0.92
13 Industrials Hot rolled Coil 0.06 1.60 −0.03 0.05 2.15 0.04 0.05 1.85 0.09 0.27 0.14 0.83
14 Industrials LLDPE 0.00 1.41 0.01 0.00 1.74 0.00 0.06 2.35 0.04 0.24 0.19 0.68
15 Industrials Methanol −0.01 1.40 0.04 −0.01 1.47 0.01 0.03 2.02 0.09 0.22 0.20 0.71
16 Industrials PP 0.04 1.31 0.05 0.02 1.55 0.02 0.05 1.84 0.08 0.17 0.17 0.67
17 Industrials Natural Rubber −0.02 1.89 0.01 0.00 2.96 0.01 0.07 2.06 0.07 0.32 0.21 0.60
18 Industrials PTA −0.01 1.34 0.03 0.02 1.84 0.00 0.06 2.24 0.09 0.24 0.22 0.71
19 Industrials PVC 0.00 1.10 0.00 0.01 1.45 0.02 0.03 1.80 0.05 0.23 0.25 0.71
20 Energy Bitumen −0.04 1.68 0.01 0.02 2.34 0.08 0.04 1.90 0.09 0.19 0.18 0.82
21 Energy Coke 0.01 1.79 −0.01 −0.01 1.84 0.03 0.00 1.93 0.03 0.26 0.24 0.87
22 Energy Coking coal 0.03 1.83 −0.05 0.01 1.90 0.04 0.03 2.06 0.04 0.23 0.20 0.88
23 Energy Thermal coal 0.04 1.21 −0.05 0.03 1.92 0.03 0.04 1.76 0.07 0.18 0.11 0.93
24 Agriculture No. 1 soybean 0.01 1.10 −0.06 0.09 2.52 0.06 0.07 2.22 0.08 0.15 0.16 0.82
25 Agriculture No. 2 soybean 0.02 1.30 −0.03 0.09 2.52 0.06 0.07 2.22 0.08 0.10 0.12 0.82
26 Agriculture Corn 0.01 0.73 −0.06 0.08 2.45 0.07 0.08 2.10 0.08 0.11 0.12 0.82
27 Agriculture Cotton −0.01 1.09 0.00 0.08 2.34 0.09 0.06 2.19 0.09 0.16 0.15 0.85
28 Agriculture Corn starch 0.00 0.94 0.03 0.00 2.17 0.10 0.07 2.16 0.09 0.03 0.03 0.89
29 Agriculture Egg −0.01 1.24 −0.01 0.11 2.50 0.10 0.07 2.03 0.12 0.10 0.09 0.72
30 Agriculture Soybean meal 0.04 1.31 −0.03 0.08 2.25 0.08 0.08 2.17 0.08 0.14 0.13 0.97
31 Agriculture Rapeseed oil 0.00 1.18 0.00 0.06 2.63 0.07 0.04 2.70 0.04 0.20 0.18 0.62
32 Agriculture Palm oil −0.02 1.39 0.01 0.01 2.90 0.10 0.03 2.97 0.05 0.21 0.16 0.55
33 Agriculture Rapeseed meal 0.04 1.31 −0.01 0.05 2.39 0.05 0.07 1.99 0.11 0.09 0.06 0.73
34 Agriculture White sugar 0.00 1.18 −0.01 0.10 2.28 0.11 0.08 1.96 0.08 0.19 0.15 0.87
35 Agriculture Wheat WH −0.01 0.75 −0.05 0.07 2.62 0.06 0.08 1.99 0.07 0.11 0.10 0.74
36 Agriculture Soybean oil 0.00 1.23 −0.01 0.07 2.63 0.14 0.07 3.05 0.05 0.18 0.17 0.60
  • Note: This table reports the summary statistics including the mean (Mean), standard deviation (SD), first-order autocorrelation (AR1) for all the selected commodity futures returns, together with the related supplier-side stock portfolio returns and customer-side stock portfolio returns. In addition, the correlation among three time-series returns for each commodity are also presented. The full sample period covers Jan 2005–Dec 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period.

3 IN-SAMPLE REGRESSION RESULTS

3.1 Univariate regression results

We first rely on the standard univariate regression model in Equation (1) to examine the predictability of commodity futures returns for equity portfolio returns.
R i , t + 1 = α + β i R _ com i , t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T 1 (1)
where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , supplier , t + 1 (or R i , customer , t + 1 ), which is commodity i's supplier-side (or customer-side) stock portfolio return in excess of the risk-free rate at time t + 1; R _ com i , t is commodity i's excess futures return at time t, which acts as the predictor; and ε i , t + 1 is a zero-mean disturbance term. We select the 1-year deposit rate published by the People's Bank of China as the proxy for the risk-free rate in China's financial market.

The null hypothesis is that the commodity futures returns R _ com i , t have no predictive ability for supplier-side (customer-side) equity portfolio returns. The existing empirical evidence for stock markets (e.g., C. Li et al., 2020; Menzly & Ozbas, 2010; Shahrur et al., 2010) suggests positive signs of the β i s for both the supplier side and customer side, which is consistent with the underreaction hypothesis. From the macroeconomic perspective, increases in commodity prices indicate a strengthened expectation of the future economy, and most of the macropredictors can positively predict the equity risk premium (Goyal & Welch, 2008). Following the theoretical and empirical evidence, we implement one-sided tests for H0 :  β i 0 against the alternative HA: β i > 0 using the Newey and West (1987) heteroskedasticity-consistent t-statistic.

Table 3 presents the estimation results of the in-sample univariate predictive regression, and the significance levels are accessed based on one-sided test statistics. When predicting the supplier-side equity returns, we find that 9 of the 11 metal futures (silver, aluminum, copper, iron ore, nickel, lead, steel rebar, tin, and zinc), 7 of the 8 industrial futures (glass, hot rolled coil, LLDPE, methanol, PP, natural rubber, and PTA), all the energy futures (bitumen, coke, coking coal, and thermal coal) and 7 of the 13 agriculture futures (No. 1 soybeans, corn, cotton, rapeseed meal, white sugar, wheat WH, and soybean oil) exhibit significantly positive estimates for β. Moreover, 35 of 36 commodity futures exhibit positive estimates for β on the supplier-side, which is consistent with economic theory. The adjusted R 2 shown in the fifth column of Table 3 is relatively small, with an average of 0.24% for the significant predictors. Campbell and Thompson (2008) document that an R 2 less than 1% can be economically significant since a substantially unpredictable component is contained within the stock returns. If a high R 2 is easily obtained, this will lead investors to suspect that highly outstanding predictive regressions are spurious as such a case would be too profitable to believe. Therefore, the magnitude of R 2 in our result is reasonable and consistent with previous studies.

Table 3. Univariate in-sample predictive regression estimation results
No. Futures category Futures name Supplier Customer
β ˆ i , supplier t-stat Adj . R 2 ( % ) β ˆ i , customer t-stat Adj . R 2 ( % )
1 Metals Silver 0.088** [2.11] 0.22 0.051* [1.61] 0.04
2 Metals Aluminum 0.079* [1.58] 0.07 −0.038 [−1.02] 0.01
3 Metals Gold 0.023 [0.47] −0.02 0.039 [0.72] 0.00
4 Metals Copper 0.058* [1.60] 0.08 −0.014 [−0.54] −0.02
5 Metals Iron ore 0.076*** [2.57] 0.39 0.061*** [2.60] 0.30
6 Metals Nickel 0.076* [1.31] 0.11 0.091* [1.52] 0.25
7 Metals Lead 0.084** [1.91] 0.12 0.002 [0.08] −0.05
8 Metals Steel rebar 0.079*** [2.76] 0.27 0.034* [1.31] 0.04
9 Metals Silicon manganese 0.022 [0.46] −0.06 0.015 [0.38] −0.06
10 Metals Tin 0.231*** [2.56] 0.74 0.237*** [2.80] 0.80
11 Metals Zinc 0.146*** [4.08] 0.61 0.000 [0.00] −0.03
12 Industrials Glass 0.101*** [2.44] 0.38 0.106*** [3.08] 0.51
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil 0.095*** [2.62] 0.42 0.038 [1.05] 0.04
14 Industrials LLDPE 0.060** [2.13] 0.20 0.038 [1.11] 0.02
15 Industrials Methanol 0.062*** [2.57] 0.31 0.069** [1.82] 0.18
16 Industrials PP 0.062** [1.85] 0.20 0.037 [0.90] 0.00
17 Industrials Natural rubber 0.129*** [3.59] 0.58 0.029* [1.41] 0.05
18 Industrials PTA 0.038* [1.34] 0.05 0.026 [0.71] −0.01
19 Industrials PVC 0.012 [0.43] −0.03 0.039 [1.08] 0.02
20 Energy Bitumen 0.097** [2.19] 0.42 0.099*** [2.47] 0.71
21 Energy Coke 0.046*** [2.38] 0.15 0.035** [1.77] 0.06
22 Energy Coking coal 0.074*** [3.51] 0.45 0.060*** [2.59] 0.23
23 Energy Thermal coal 0.083*** [2.38] 0.21 0.061** [1.94] 0.11
24 Agriculture No. 1 soybean 0.075* [1.35] 0.08 0.028 [0.64] −0.01
25 Agriculture No. 2 soybean 0.018 [0.48] −0.02 0.005 [0.16] −0.03
26 Agriculture Corn 0.164*** [2.54] 0.21 0.143*** [2.57] 0.22
27 Agriculture Cotton 0.057** [1.75] 0.04 −0.012 [−0.42] −0.02
28 Agriculture Corn starch 0.047 [0.86] −0.04 0.071* [1.31] 0.02
29 Agriculture Egg −0.004 [-0.09] −0.07 −0.003 [−0.09] −0.07
30 Agriculture Soybean meal 0.026 [0.75] −0.01 0.022 [0.69] −0.01
31 Agriculture Rapeseed oil 0.036 [0.70] −0.01 0.027 [0.55] −0.02
32 Agriculture Palm oil 0.044 [0.90] 0.01 0.052 [0.99] 0.02
33 Agriculture Rapeseed meal 0.064* [1.33] 0.07 0.029 [0.70] −0.02
34 Agriculture White sugar 0.071** [1.74] 0.10 −0.016 [−0.48] −0.02
35 Agriculture Wheat WH 0.154*** [2.41] 0.16 0.086* [1.63] 0.08
36 Agriculture Soybean oil 0.065* [1.39] 0.06 0.074* [1.32] 0.06
  • Note: This table reports the estimation results of univariate in-sample predictive regression model: R i , t + 1 = α + β i R _ com i , t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1, 2, 3 , T 1, where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , supplier , t + 1 (or R i , customer , t + 1 ) which is the commodity i's supplier-side (or customer-side) excess stock portfolio return at time t+1; R _ com i , t is the commodity i's excess futures return at time t which acts as the predictor; and ε i , t + 1 is a zero-mean disturbance term. We implement one-sided tests for H0: β i 0 against the alternative HA: β i > 0, using the Newey-West (1987) t-statistics and adjusted R 2 . *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan. 2005–Dec. 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period.

The predictability of commodity futures returns for customer-side stock returns is less significant than that for the supplier-side. As presented in Tables 3 and 5 metal futures (silver, iron ore, nickel, steel rebar, and tin), three industrial futures (glass, methanol, and natural rubber), all the energy futures (bitumen, coke, coking coal, and thermal coal) and four agriculture futures (corn, corn starch, wheat WH, and soybean oil) exhibit significantly positive estimates for β while 30 out of 36 futures exhibit positive estimates β. In summary, our result indicates that commodity futures exhibit predictive power for stock returns along the supply chain, especially on the supplier side.

Table 4. Multivariate in-sample results controlling common factors
Supplier Customer
No. Futures category Futures name β ˆ i , supplier t-stat Adj . R 2 ( % ) β ˆ i , customer t-stat Adj . R 2 ( % )
1 Metals Silver 0.052** [1.91] 58.70 0.023 [0.92] 40.40
2 Metals Aluminum 0.123*** [4.51] 66.13 0.004 [0.37] 88.86
3 Metals Gold 0.022 [1.04] 69.90 0.038* [1.37] 66.45
4 Metals Copper 0.076*** [3.67] 63.70 0.003 [0.28] 82.75
5 Metals Iron ore 0.052*** [3.27] 61.10 0.018* [1.37] 68.82
6 Metals Nickel 0.018 [0.63] 70.07 0.041* [1.35] 67.97
7 Metals Lead 0.076*** [2.77] 65.10 −0.003 [−0.35] 90.51
8 Metals Steel rebar 0.049*** [3.46] 73.49 0.006 [0.87] 91.74
9 Metals Silicon manganese −0.030 [−1.09] 66.54 −0.034 [−1.56] 69.42
10 Metals Tin 0.136** [2.16] 53.91 0.142*** [2.64] 65.08
11 Metals Zinc 0.137*** [6.41] 64.87 −0.003 [−0.40] 91.06
12 Industrials Glass 0.004 [0.35] 90.29 0.005 [0.60] 93.39
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil 0.045*** [2.43] 71.55 −0.006 [−0.94] 95.33
14 Industrials LLDPE 0.033*** [3.07] 77.52 −0.004 [−0.23] 59.58
15 Industrials Methanol 0.035*** [3.64] 81.23 0.019* [1.58] 85.85
16 Industrials PP 0.024** [1.68] 75.09 −0.005 [−0.57] 94.64
17 Industrials Natural rubber 0.069*** [2.56] 39.38 −0.013 [−2.09] 88.76
18 Industrials PTA 0.033*** [2.77] 76.87 0.010 [1.12] 90.73
19 Industrials PVC 0.007 [0.53] 74.04 0.001 [0.08] 88.33
20 Energy Bitumen 0.009 [0.48] 78.85 0.016 [0.96] 77.58
21 Energy Coke 0.011* [1.44] 78.50 0.002 [0.19] 67.22
22 Energy Coking coal 0.012 [1.10] 77.98 −0.002 [−0.12] 66.62
23 Energy Thermal coal 0.029* [1.55] 77.71 0.012* [1.39] 91.11
24 Agriculture No. 1 soybean 0.070** [2.09] 60.39 0.024* [1.37] 78.22
25 Agriculture No. 2 soybean 0.032* [1.28] 60.33 0.020* [1.51] 78.22
26 Agriculture Corn 0.069** [1.70] 62.83 0.041* [1.35] 75.86
27 Agriculture Cotton 0.063*** [2.80] 69.75 −0.005 [−0.56] 90.43
28 Agriculture Corn starch −0.011 [−0.34] 74.54 0.013 [0.48] 75.69
29 Agriculture Egg −0.004 [−0.09] 35.85 −0.002 [−0.13] 79.86
30 Agriculture Soybean meal 0.027** [1.76] 74.32 0.023* [1.53] 74.89
31 Agriculture Rapeseed oil 0.047* [1.51] 55.97 0.045* [1.48] 61.81
32 Agriculture Palm oil 0.048** [1.67] 56.47 0.061** [1.74] 46.77
33 Agriculture Rapeseed meal 0.037 [1.04] 53.16 0.003 [0.13] 71.56
34 Agriculture White sugar 0.084*** [3.52] 70.59 −0.004 [−0.32] 84.18
35 Agriculture Wheat WH 0.112*** [2.88] 50.97 0.045** [1.87] 77.94
36 Agriculture Soybean oil 0.048** [2.17] 65.88 0.066** [1.81] 47.62
  • Note: This table reports the estimation results of multivariate in-sample predictive regression model by adding common pricing factors: R i , t + 1 = α + β i R com i , t + β MKT MKT t + 1 + β SMB SMB t + 1 + β HML HML t + 1 + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , T 1 , where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , supplier , t + 1 (or R i , customer , t + 1 ) which is the commodity i's supplier-side (or customer-side) excess stock portfolio return at time t + 1; R _ com i , t is the commodity i's excess futures return at time t which acts as the predictor; MKT t + 1 SMB t + 1 and HML t + 1 are common pricing factors at time t + 1, which are constructed following Fama and French (1993); ε i , t + 1 is zero-mean disturbance term. We implement one-sided tests for H0: β i 0 against the alternative HA: β i > 0, using the Newey-West (1987) t-statistics and adjusted R 2 . *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan. 2005–Dec. 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period.
Table 5. In-sample results controlling overall macroeconomic risk: supplier-side
No. Futures category Futures name β ˆ i , supplier t-stat β ˆ i , pc_com t-stat Adj . R 2 ( % )
1 Metals Silver 0.029 [0.63] 0.052*** [3.48] 0.95
2 Metals Aluminum −0.002 [−0.03] 0.035*** [2.57] 0.23
3 Metals Gold −0.007 [−0.12] 0.025** [2.10] 0.16
4 Metals Copper −0.038 [−0.78] 0.052*** [2.99] 0.37
5 Metals Iron ore 0.004 [0.11] 0.048** [2.27] 0.69
6 Metals Nickel 0.048 [0.77] 0.015 [0.67] 0.06
7 Metals Lead −0.032 [−0.55] 0.055*** [3.03] 0.71
8 Metals Steel rebar 0.036 [0.81] 0.020 [1.25] 0.32
9 Metals Silicon manganese −0.027 [−0.52] 0.048*** [2.64] 0.55
10 Metals Tin 0.146* [1.59] 0.037** [1.89] 0.91
11 Metals Zinc 0.085* [1.64] 0.033** [1.69] 0.71
12 Industrials Glass 0.084** [1.83] 0.009 [0.56] 0.35
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil 0.030 [0.52] 0.032* [1.44] 0.56
14 Industrials LLDPE 0.050 [1.27] 0.005 [0.42] 0.18
15 Industrials Methanol 0.013 [0.52] 0.028*** [2.59] 0.64
16 Industrials PP −0.023 [−0.58] 0.039*** [2.99] 0.86
17 Industrials Natural rubber 0.128*** [2.42] 0.000 [0.02] 0.53
18 Industrials PTA 0.010 [0.28] 0.015* [1.43] 0.09
19 Industrials PVC −0.076 [-2.52] 0.037*** [3.91] 0.61
20 Energy Bitumen 0.076** [1.76] 0.014 [0.84] 0.39
21 Energy Coke −0.006 [−0.19] 0.033** [2.08] 0.41
22 Energy Coking coal 0.027 [0.93] 0.030** [1.75] 0.64
23 Energy Thermal coal 0.027 [0.70] 0.033** [2.32] 0.56
24 Agricultural No. 1 soybean 0.023 [0.38] 0.023** [1.81] 0.14
25 Agricultural No. 2 soybean −0.020 [−0.54] 0.029*** [2.34] 0.14
26 Agricultural Corn 0.126** [1.85] 0.016 [1.22] 0.24
27 Agricultural Cotton 0.020 [0.57] 0.020* [1.58] 0.12
28 Agricultural Corn starch 0.008 [0.13] 0.030** [1.83] 0.27
29 Agricultural Egg −0.011 [−0.24] 0.007 [0.44] −0.12
30 Agricultural Soybean meal −0.002 [−0.06] 0.015 [1.13] 0.01
31 Agricultural Rapeseed oil −0.056 [−0.93] 0.037*** [2.37] 0.16
32 Agricultural Palm oil 0.000 [0.00] 0.020 [1.21] 0.02
33 Agricultural Rapeseed meal 0.002 [0.05] 0.042*** [2.65] 0.45
34 Agricultural White sugar 0.041 [0.90] 0.019* [1.54] 0.17
35 Agricultural Wheat WH 0.107** [1.65] 0.026** [1.91] 0.29
36 Agricultural Soybean oil 0.016 [0.26] 0.020* [1.30] 0.09
  • Note: This table reports the estimation results of supplier-side in-sample predictive regression model by adding principle component factor: R i , t + 1 = α + β i R com i , t + β PC PC_com t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T 1 , where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , supplier , t + 1 which is the commodity i's supplier-side excess stock portfolio return at time t + 1; R _ com i , t is the commodity i's excess futures return at time t which acts as the predictor; PC_com t is the first principle component of all the commodity futures returns at time t; ε i , t + 1 is zero-mean disturbance term. We implement one-sided tests for H0 :  β i 0 against the alternative HA :  β i > 0, using the Newey-West (1987) t-statistics and adjusted R 2 . *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan 2005–Dec 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period.

The positive estimates for β of most commodity futures are consistent with the underreaction hypothesis and the positive correlation between commodity prices and macroeconomic conditions. Ferson et al. (2003) document that the statistical inference of running an in-sample predictive regression is disturbed when the predictor is highly persistent and correlated with the excess market return. To address this bias, we follow Neely et al. (2014) and run 5,000 simulations to calculate the wild bootstrapped p value for each regression. The results of the wild bootstrapped p values are similar with those tabulated in Table 3, and thus, our use of the t-statistic is considered substantially robust in the in-sample univariate regression.

3.2 Multivariate regression results after controlling common pricing factors

To examine whether the predictive content from the commodity-related predictor repeats that from the popular pricing factors, we utilize a multivariate regression form (Stambaugh et al., 2012), which includes the market risk factor (MKT), the market capitalization risk factor (SMB) and the book-to-market risk factor (HML).
R i , t + 1 = α + β i R com i , t + β MKT MKT t + 1 + β SMB SMB t + 1 + β HML HML t + 1 + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T 1 , (2)
where MKT t + 1 , SMB t + 1 and HML t + 1 are constructed following Fama and French (1993).

Table 4 reports the in-sample multivariate regression results after controlling these common pricing factors. For the supplier-side equity return predictability, the estimated β loses its significance for five commodities including nickel, glass, bitumen, coking coal, and rapeseed meal while 3 of 36 futures exhibit insignificant negative estimates for β after controlling common pricing factors. The remaining 22 significant estimates for β in both univariate and multivariate regressions indicate that the commodity futures can predict the supplier-side equity portfolio returns, even after controlling common sources of return variation. On the customer side, eight commodity futures (silver, steel rebar, glass, natural rubber, bitumen, coke, coking coal, and corn starch) lose their statistical significance after controlling these three pricing factors. It is further noted that the in-sample predictive significance of energy futures is substantially subsumed by common factors in the multivariate regressions for both the supplier side and customer side. This may indicate that energy commodity information has a higher correlation with the classical risk factor of the stock market.

3.3 Regression results considering overall macroeconomic risk

Considering that commodity futures returns are highly correlated, in this section we follow Neely et al. (2014) and use the principle component analysis (PCA) to extract the first component of all the commodity futures returns and thus form the time-series PC _ com t . By adding this variable as an additional predictor variable, we can control an overall macroeconomic risk premium effect to describe the aggregate commodity demand (Alquist et al., 2020).
R i , t + 1 = α + β i R com i , t + β PC PC _ com t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T 1 , (3)
where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , supplier , t + 1 (or R i , customer , t + 1 ) which is the commodity i's supplier-side (or customer-side) excess stock portfolio return at time t + 1; R _ com i , t is the commodity i's excess futures return at time t which acts as the predictor; PC _ com t is the first principle component of all the commodity futures returns at time t.

The results in Table 5 and 6 represent the bivariate in-sample regressions for supplier-side and customer-side, respectively. We find that 26 of the supplier-side β ˆ PC s and 20 of the customer-side β ˆ PC s exhibit significant estimates, meaning that the overall macroeconomic risk represented by the aggregate commodity demand is an important source of the cross-market supply-chain predictability. While in many cases, the idiosyncratic effect measured by β ˆ i , supplier or β ˆ i , customer loses its statistical significance, we find that seven commodities (i.e., tin, zinc, glass, natural rubber, bitumen, corn, and wheat WH) still obtain significant β ˆ i , suppli er , and seven commodities (i.e., tin, glass, LLDPE, natural rubber, bitumen, corn, and wheat WH) obtain significant β ˆ i , customer .

Table 6. In-sample results controlling overall macroeconomic risk: customer-side
No. Futures category Futures name β ˆ i , customer t-stat β ˆ i , pc_com t-stat Adj . R 2 ( % )
1 Metals Silver 0.017 [0.46] 0.029** [2.13] 0.26
2 Metals Aluminum −0.095 [−2.18] 0.024** [2.22] 0.15
3 Metals Gold 0.022 [0.39] 0.014 [1.28] 0.04
4 Metals Copper −0.064 [−1.82] 0.027** [2.13] 0.12
5 Metals Iron ore 0.010 [0.27] 0.035** [1.72] 0.47
6 Metals Nickel 0.027 [0.42] 0.036** [2.11] 0.44
7 Metals Lead −0.070 [−1.59] 0.034*** [2.35] 0.38
8 Metals Steel rebar −0.010 [−0.30] 0.021* [1.54] 0.13
9 Metals Silicon manganese −0.027 [−0.60] 0.042*** [2.78] 0.52
10 Metals Tin 0.151** [1.69] 0.037** [1.92] 0.97
11 Metals Zinc −0.026 [−0.75] 0.013 [0.97] -0.02
12 Industrials Glass 0.076** [1.98] 0.015 [1.11] 0.54
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil −0.019 [−0.40] 0.028* [1.53] 0.18
14 Industrials LLDPE 0.062* [1.38] −0.012 [-0.79] 0.01
15 Industrials Methanol 0.043 [1.11] 0.015 [0.98] 0.19
16 Industrials PP −0.006 [−0.13] 0.020 [1.27] 0.06
17 Industrials Natural rubber 0.045* [1.47] −0.010 [-0.68] 0.04
18 Industrials PTA 0.014 [0.35] 0.006 [0.53] -0.03
19 Industrials PVC −0.005 [−0.13] 0.018* [1.65] 0.09
20 Energy Bitumen 0.067** [1.70] 0.021* [1.59] 0.78
21 Energy Coke −0.029 [−0.90] 0.042*** [2.51] 0.45
22 Energy Coking coal 0.001 [0.02] 0.038** [2.11] 0.50
23 Energy Thermal coal 0.012 [0.37] 0.028** [2.01] 0.41
24 Agricultural No. 1 soybean −0.005 [−0.09] 0.014 [1.20] 0.01
25 Agricultural No. 2 soybean −0.015 [−0.44] 0.015* [1.35] 0.01
26 Agricultural Corn 0.128** [2.10] 0.006 [0.57] 0.20
27 Agricultural Cotton −0.036 [−1.13] 0.014 [1.09] 0.00
28 Agricultural Corn starch 0.050 [0.89] 0.017 [1.09] 0.06
29 Agricultural Egg −0.031 [−0.90] 0.027** [1.70] 0.16
30 Agricultural Soybean meal −0.009 [−0.24] 0.017 [1.28] 0.03
31 Agricultural Rapeseed oil −0.039 [−0.66] 0.026** [1.84] 0.05
32 Agricultural Palm oil −0.012 [−0.19] 0.029** [1.75] 0.08
33 Agricultural Rapeseed meal −0.009 [−0.20] 0.026** [1.76] 0.16
34 Agricultural White sugar −0.035 [−0.90] 0.012 [1.07] 0.00
35 Agricultural Wheat WH 0.073* [1.35] 0.007 [0.70] 0.07
36 Agricultural Soybean oil 0.044 [0.64] 0.012 [0.68] 0.04
  • Note: This table reports the estimation results of customer-side in-sample predictive regression model by adding principle component factor: R i , t + 1 = α + β i R com i , t + β PC PC_com t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , T 1 , where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , customer , t + 1 which is the commodity i's customer-side excess stock portfolio return at time t + 1; R _ com i , t is the commodity i's excess futures return at time t which acts as the predictor; PC_com t is the first principle component of all the commodity futures returns at time t; ε i , t + 1 is zero-mean disturbance term. We implement one-sided tests for H0 :  β i 0 against the alternative HA :  β i > 0, using the Newey-West (1987) t-statistics and adjusted R 2 . *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan 2005–Dec 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period.

3.4 Pooled regression results

In this section, we use the pooled regression to examine how strong the estimated effects are on average. First, we implement a pooled regression in Equation (4) that includes all observations, together with separate pooled regressions for suppliers and customers.
R i , t + 1 = α + β i R c o m i , t + δ i R i , t + ε i , t + 1 , f o r t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T 1 , (4)
where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , supplier , t + 1 ( or R i , customer , t + 1 ), which is commodity i's supplier-side (or customer-side) stock portfolio return in excess of the risk-free rate at time t + 1; R _ com i , t is commodity i's excess futures return at time t, which acts as the predictor; the predictive regression also contains the excess equity return R i , t at time t, as the control variable.

We replicate the regressions that include individual and time fixed effects, and the regression results are tabulated in columns 2–7 of Table 7. This result confirms the average effects across all the commodities as evidenced by the statistically significant estimates of β at the 1% level. Similarly, the coefficient of supplier-side is larger than that of customer-side in the pooled regression with or without including fixed effects.

Table 7. Pooled in-sample regression results
Pooled regression Pooled regression with fixed effects
Both sides Supplier-side Customer-side Both sides Supplier-side Customer-side Supplier-side Customer-side
Constant 0.0004*** 0.0003*** 0.0004*** 0.0004*** 0.0003*** 0.0004*** 0.0003*** 0.0004***
(5.53) (4.30) (6.11) (13.43) (7.90) (13.48) (7.93) (13.48)
R_com i , t 0.0297*** 0.0433*** 0.0169*** 0.0136*** 0.0195*** 0.0078***
(5.12) (6.50) (2.88) (5.01) (4.75) (2.64)
R_com i , t CONC i , low , , t 0.0023 0.0012
(0.37) (0.32)
R_com i , t CONC i , med , t 0.0102** 0.0056*
(1.78) (1.54)
R_com i , t CONC i , high , t 0.0548*** 0.0170***
(6.98) (2.57)
R i , t 0.0634*** 0.0614*** 0.0651*** 0.0408*** 0.0395*** 0.0491*** 0.0384*** 0.0487***
(12.84) (11.46) (11.84) (9.13) (7.23) (7.15) (7.03) (7.10)
Commodity FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Time FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes
Obs. 188,314 93,436 94,878 188,314 93,436 94,878 93,436 94,878
Adj . R 2 (%) 0.48 0.50 0.46 71.84 68.92 78.38 68.93 78.38
  • Note: This table reports the estimation results of pooled regression for predicting prospective supply-chain equity returns using commodity returns. In the columns 2-7, we implement pooled regression without and with controlling fixed effects, for both sides or individual side along the supply chain: R i , t + 1 = α + β i R com i , t + γ i R i , t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T 1 , where R i , t + 1 refers to R i , supplier , t + 1 (or R i , customer , t + 1 ), which is commodity i's supplier-side (or customer-side) stock portfolio return in excess of the risk-free rate at time t + 1 while R _ com i , t is commodity i's excess futures return at time t, which acts as the predictor, together with the control variable R i , t . In the columns 8-9, we augment the pooled regression for individual side: R i , t + 1 = α + β i , low R com i , t Conc i , low , t + β i , med R com i , t Conc i , med , t + β i , high R com i , t Conc i , high , t + δ i R i , t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T , where we sort all the observations by Conc i , supplier , t ( or Conc i , customer , t ) into low 30%, medium 40% and high 30% groups. If the level of Conc i , supplier , t ( or Conc i , customer , t ) for commodity i at time t places this observation in one of these three groups, we define the related concentration dummy variable (i.e., Conc i , low , t , Conc i , med , t , and Conc i , high , t ) as one and zero otherwise. We report one-sided robust t-statistics in parentheses and adjusted R 2 . *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan 2005–Dec 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period.

The asymmetric predictability of commodity futures between supplier-side and customer-side equity portfolios may be due to the different responses of the expected cash flow to the commodity price shocks. Since commodities act as the output products for supplier-side firms, increases in commodity prices benefit the prospective revenue or cash flows of these firms and thus positively contribute to the stock prices. However, for customer-side firms, increases in commodity prices will improve the expected expenditures for these firms and weaken the positive equity return predictability when using the commodity-related predictor. Therefore, we obtain stronger cross-market return predictability for the supplier-side firms than the customer-side firms.

Another potential explanation for this predictability asymmetry may be that suppliers are often more concentrated on and thus exposed to one or few selected commodities, whereas for many customers, commodities are only a fraction of their costs. As a result, the supplier-side stock prices are more sensitive to the shock of commodity prices than the consumer-side stock prices.

Actually, we can see from Table 1, the supplier-side firms are less than customer-side firms for 27 out of 36 commodities. To test the above hypothesis, we define the concentration of supplier-side firms ( C onc i , supplier , t ) as the ratio of commodity i's customer-side firm number to supplier-side firm number at time t, and a relatively smaller number of suppliers refers to a higher C onc i , supplier , t . Similarly, Conc i , customer , t is the defined as 1 / C onc i , supplier , t . We sort all the observations by Conc i , supplier , t ( or Conc i , customer , t ) into three groups: low 30%, medium 40% and high 30%. If the level of Conc i , supplier , t ( or Conc i , customer , t ) for commodity i at time t places the observation in one of the three groups, we define its concentration dummy variable (i.e., Conc i , low , t , Conc i , med , t , and Conc i , high , t ) as one and zero otherwise.

We multiply the main predictor R com i , t by the concentration dummy variable, and augment the pooled regression using Equation (5),
R i , t + 1 = α + β i , low R com i , t Conc i , low , t + β i , med R com i , t Conc i , med , t + β i , high R com i , t Conc i , high , t + δ i R i , t + ε i , t + 1 , for t = 1 , 2 , 3 , , T (5)

The estimation results in the last two columns of Table 7 show that observations with more concentrated firms, on either side, can acquire more significant estimate of β. This result indicates that the prices of more concentrated firms are more influenced by the commodity prices. Moreover, for the same interaction term, the supplier-side estimate for β is more significant and larger than that of customer-side, which further indicates that more concentrated supplier-side firms exhibit more significant return predictability.

4 OUT-OF-SAMPLE TESTS

4.1 Preliminary evidence of forecasting results

To further examine the forecasting performance of this supply-chain predictor, we implement the out-of-sample predictive exercise using commodity futures returns. The out-of-sample equity risk premium forecast R ˆ i , t + 1 on day t + 1, which can be R ˆ i , supplier , t + 1 or R ˆ i , customer , t + 1 , is obtained using Equation (6), where α ˆ i , t + 1 and β ˆ i , t + 1 are the OLS estimates from regressing { R i , d } d = 2 t on a constant and { R_com i , d } d = 1 t 1 . The full sample periods for different commodity futures vary from 1,165 to 3,648 days, and thus, we accordingly adjust the out-of-sample evaluation periods for each commodity. We set the initial in-sample period as 2 years (500 daily observations). To continue this out-of-sample forecasting methodology, we generate time-series forecasts, as follows.
R ˆ i , t + 1 = α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t . (6)
The benchmark forecast is the historical average of the stock portfolio returns in Equation (7), which outperforms the forecasting results using numerous predictors (see, e.g., Campbell & Thompson, 2008; Goyal & Welch, 2008).
R ˆ i , t + 1 HA = R ¯ i , t + 1 = ( 1 / t ) d = 1 t R i , d . (7)
To evaluate the forecasting results, we use the Campbell and Thompson (2008) out-of-sample R OS 2 statistic defined as follows:
R i , OS 2 = 1 MSFE i , model MSFE i , bench , (8)
where MSFE i , model = 1 T D t = D + 1 T ( R i , t R ˆ i , t ) 2 and MSFE i , bench = 1 T D t = D + 1 T ( R i , t R ¯ i , t ) 2 are mean squared forecast errors of our selected forecasting model and the benchmark model of historical average returns, respectively. Accordingly, the R i , OS 2 statistic in Equation (8) measures the proportional reduction in the MSFE of the selected forecasting model relative to the benchmark model. Therefore, a positive R i , OS 2 statistic indicates that our forecasting result outperforms the benchmark in terms of the MSFE for the specific commodity i.
Let
f i , t = ( R i , t R ¯ i , t ) 2 ( R i , t R ˆ i , t ) 2 + ( R ¯ i , t R ˆ i , t ) 2 . (9)

By regressing { f i , t } t + 1 T on a constant, we can get the t-statistic of the constant, which is called the CW (Clark & West, 2007) statistic. This statistic is used to test the null hypothesis that the MSFE of the benchmark model is less than or equal to the MSFE of our selected forecasting model against the one-sided alternative hypothesis that the former term is larger than the latter term. This is consistent with assessing H0 :  R i , OS 2 0 against the alternative HA :  R i , OS 2 > 0.

Table 8 presents the out-the-sample results of this unrestricted OLS predictor. For both the supplier-side and customer-side equities, the MSFEs of the benchmark model and our model, the R OS 2 s and the CW statistics are reported. It is well known that the in-sample return predictability cannot guarantee outstanding out-of-sample performance. Compared with the in-sample estimation result, the number of commodity futures with significant out-of-sample performance is reduced since the historical average is a stringent benchmark in the equity market. The average R OS 2 is −0.062% for supplier-side forecasts and −0.216% for customer-side forecasts. Therefore, the cross-market supply-chain forecasting model using this naïve strategy cannot easily beat the benchmark model for most commodities. Importantly, we find that the out-of-sample performance varies for different commodities. When forecasting the supplier-side equities, we find that five metal futures (silver, iron ore, nickel, steel rebar, and zinc), four industrial futures (glass, LLDPE, methanol, and natural rubber), two energy futures (coking coal and thermal coal), and two agriculture futures (corn and wheat WH) obtain significantly positive R OS 2 s with an average of 0.249%. For the customer-side equities, the predictability is significant for five commodity futures (iron ore, glass, methanol, coking coal, and corn) with an average R OS 2 of 0.194%. In particular, the commodity futures of iron ore, glass, methanol, coking coal, and corn have significant out-of-sample predictive power for both supplier-side and customer-side equity returns and these commodity futures also obtain significant estimates of β at the 1% level in the univariate regressions. Therefore, the out-of-sample tests further indicate that a number of commodity futures exhibit statistically significant equity return predictability along the supply chain, especially on the supplier side.

Table 8. Out-of-sample performance of the cross-market supply-chain predictability
Supplier Customer
No. Futures category Futures name MSFE bench MSFE model R OS 2 ( % ) CW MSFE bench MSFE model R OS 2 ( % ) CW
1 Metals Silver 5.731 5.720 0.189* 1.33 4.915 4.917 −0.022 0.33
2 Metals Aluminum 7.207 7.213 −0.083 0.31 4.250 4.253 −0.050 −0.13
3 Metals Gold 3.934 3.936 −0.027 −0.30 3.904 3.908 −0.103 −0.10
4 Metals Copper 7.798 7.796 0.019 0.96 4.210 4.213 −0.081 −0.31
5 Metals Iron ore 3.962 3.937 0.634*** 2.42 3.288 3.276 0.360*** 2.36
6 Metals Nickel 4.550 4.538 0.277* 1.47 2.944 2.949 −0.157 1.05
7 Metals Lead 5.641 5.640 0.009 0.68 3.073 3.079 −0.185 −2.20
8 Metals Steel rebar 3.825 3.817 0.206** 2.19 2.876 2.877 −0.051 0.86
9 Metals Silicon manganese 3.517 3.524 −0.217 −0.50 2.433 2.435 −0.077 −0.36
10 Metals Tin 3.912 3.938 −0.662 0.60 3.890 3.920 −0.765 0.46
11 Metals Zinc 6.528 6.526 0.022** 2.16 3.311 3.313 −0.061 0.00
12 Industrials Glass 4.474 4.461 0.291*** 2.47 3.651 3.635 0.447*** 2.93
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil 2.551 2.614 −2.465 1.17 1.506 1.568 −4.126 −1.01
14 Industrials LLDPE 2.085 2.079 0.258** 2.13 4.469 4.469 −0.001 0.38
15 Industrials Methanol 2.492 2.488 0.126** 1.97 4.557 4.556 0.017** 1.74
16 Industrials PP 1.047 1.054 −0.741* 1.38 1.583 1.590 −0.444 0.93
17 Industrials Natural rubber 9.512 9.452 0.631*** 3.00 4.393 4.393 −0.018 0.46
18 Industrials PTA 2.276 2.276 0.001 0.63 3.742 3.745 −0.073 −0.59
19 Industrials PVC 1.961 1.962 −0.082 0.05 3.186 3.188 −0.049 0.77
20 Energy Bitumen 3.885 3.898 −0.319** 1.70 1.949 1.972 −1.153*** 2.38
21 Energy Coke 3.637 3.637 −0.013** 2.10 4.321 4.324 −0.072* 1.49
22 Energy Coking coal 4.046 4.038 0.220*** 2.85 5.024 5.022 0.032** 2.18
23 Energy Thermal coal 2.436 2.429 0.309** 2.00 1.777 1.778 −0.069* 1.32
24 Agriculture No. 1 soybean 6.425 6.429 −0.056 0.61 5.173 5.180 −0.134 −0.48
25 Agriculture No. 2 soybean 6.425 6.432 −0.116 −0.46 5.173 5.181 −0.153 −2.42
26 Agriculture Corn 6.092 6.088 0.064* 1.35 4.528 4.523 0.112* 1.59
27 Agriculture Cotton 5.646 5.650 −0.064 −0.02 4.980 4.985 −0.119 −0.36
28 Agriculture Corn starch 2.270 2.270 0.025 0.58 2.548 2.547 0.014 0.56
29 Agriculture Egg 4.381 4.389 −0.167 −2.06 2.616 2.621 −0.181 −2.56
30 Agriculture Soybean meal 5.241 5.248 −0.137 0.02 4.901 4.907 −0.118 0.06
31 Agriculture Rapeseed oil 5.483 5.485 −0.037 −0.42 5.893 5.894 −0.015 −0.47
32 Agriculture Palm oil 6.511 6.510 0.009 0.46 7.144 7.142 0.030 0.75
33 Agriculture Rapeseed meal 6.332 6.353 −0.322 −0.91 4.766 4.779 −0.281 −1.81
34 Agriculture White sugar 4.840 4.839 0.024 0.96 3.560 3.563 −0.097 −0.56
35 Agriculture Wheat WH 7.166 7.166 0.007* 1.64 4.117 4.119 −0.036 1.06
36 Agriculture Soybean oil 6.550 6.553 −0.052 0.39 8.604 8.612 −0.085 −0.59
Avg. −0.062 −0.216
  • Note: This table reports the out-of-sample forecasting performance using univariate predictive model for both supplier side and customer side. The forecasts R ˆ i , t + 1 is obtained from R ˆ i , t + 1 = α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t . Meanwhile, we use the historical average return R ˆ i , t + 1 HA = R ̅ i , t + 1 = ( 1 / t ) d = 1 t R i , d as the benchmark model. We calculate the mean squared forecast errors (MSFE) of our selected forecasting model and the benchmark model as MSFE i , model = 1 T D t = D + 1 T ( R i , t R ˆ i , t ) 2 and MSFE bench = 1 T D t = D + 1 T ( R i , t R ̅ i , t ) 2 for each commodity futures. The R OS 2 is thus obtained as R i , OS 2 = 1 MSFE i , model MSFE i , bench and the statistical significance is constructed following Clark and West (2007). *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan. 2005–Dec. 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period. The initial in-sample period covers two years (500 daily observations).

4.2 Economic benefits

To examine the economic benefits of using the cross-market supply-chain forecasting model rather than the benchmark model to forecast equity returns, we follow previous studies (e.g., Campbell & Thompson, 2008; Neely et al., 2014) and build a mean-variance portfolio allocation exercise. Accordingly, we are able to incorporate investors' risk aversion into the asset allocation. Our purpose is to examine the out-of-sample economic gains for the allocated portfolio if using this supply-chain forecast instead of the historical average forecast. At the end of day t, we determine the investment weights w i , t of the risky asset using Equation (10):
w i , t = ( 1 γ ) R ˆ i , t + 1 σ ˆ i , t + 1 , (10)
where γ is the risk aversion of investors, and we set it as γ = 3 here, R ˆ i , t + 1 is estimated by the model of interest, and σ ˆ i , t + 1 is the estimated volatility from the GARCH(1,1) model using the daily observations of the previous 6 months, based on the methodology of Bollerslev (1986). Accordingly, the weight allocated to the risk-free asset is ( 1 w i , t ). Here, we impose a 50% leverage ability and 50% short-sale permission of the total asset on the investors, and thus, w i , t is constrained within [−0.5,1.5]. For each commodity i, we obtain the portfolio return R i , port , t + 1 on day t + 1 using the supplier-side (or customer-side) equities and the risk-free asset in Equation (11):
R i , port , t + 1 = w i , t R i , t + 1 + R f , t + 1 , (11)
where R f , t + 1 is the risk-free asset return on day t + 1.
We use two popular economic criteria, the Sharpe ratio and the certainty equivalent return (CER), for both the supply-chain forecasting model and the historical average model. The annualized Sharpe ratio and CER and for each portfolio are calculated using Equations (12) and (13), respectively:
SR i , port = H μ ˆ i , port σ ˆ i , port , (12)
CER i , port = H ( μ ˆ i , port 1 2 γ σ ˆ i , port 2 ) , (13)
where μ ˆ i , port and σ ˆ i , port are the mean and SD, respectively, of the investor's portfolio during the out-of-sample evaluation period. H is the number of trading days in 1 year, and we set it as 250. We then compute the Sharpe ratio (or CER) gains of different forecasting strategies, which are defined as the difference between the Sharpe ratio (or CER) of the given portfolio and that of the benchmark portfolio. The CER gains can also be regarded as the portfolio management fee that investors would be willing to pay to obtain the predictive forecast instead of the forecast using the benchmark model.

Panel A of Table 9 tabulates the results of the economic gains for the allocated portfolio consisting of supplier-side equities and the risk-free asset. We briefly report the economic gains for those commodities with statistically significant and positive out-of-sample R OS 2 s. For all 13 commodity futures reported in Panel A, all the Sharpe ratio gains take positive values. Except for the commodity futures with relatively low R OS 2 s including corn, zinc, and wheat WH, all the reported commodity futures exhibit positive CER gains for the supplier-side allocated portfolios.

Table 9. Economic gains for the supply-chain forecasting model
No. Futures category Futures name R OS 2 ( % ) SR bench SR model SR gains CER bench ( % ) CER model ( % ) CER gains ( % )
Panel A: Economic gains on supplier side
1 Metals Silver 0.189* −0.919 0.807 1.726 −14.159 10.206 24.365
2 Metals Iron ore 0.634*** −0.517 0.88 1.397 −9.934 12.771 22.705
3 Metals Nickel 0.277* −0.593 0.467 1.060 −12.363 −1.226 11.137
4 Metals Steel rebar 0.206** −0.357 0.481 0.838 −4.606 0.511 5.117
5 Metals Zinc 0.022** −0.051 0.609 0.660 −2.632 −2.701 −0.069
6 Industrials Glass 0.291*** 0.281 0.571 0.290 −3.478 −2.355 1.123
7 Industrials LLDPE 0.258** 0.019 0.641 0.622 −1.56 6.315 7.875
8 Industrials Methanol 0.126** −0.115 0.314 0.429 −2.483 −0.039 2.444
9 Industrials Natural rubber 0.631*** −0.527 1.057 1.584 −17.134 17.94 35.074
10 Energy Coking coal 0.220*** −0.743 0.623 1.366 −8.590 4.133 12.723
11 Energy Thermal coal 0.309** −0.006 1.163 1.169 −3.929 20.030 23.959
12 Agriculture Corn 0.064* 0.530 0.632 0.102 1.443 −10.649 −12.092
13 Agriculture Wheat WH 0.007* 0.449 0.458 0.009 −0.813 −22.896 −22.083
Panel B: Economic gains on customer side
1 Metals Iron ore 0.360*** 0.207 0.607 0.400 −4.664 4.457 9.121
2 Industrials Glass 0.447*** 0.274 0.702 0.428 −3.697 4.688 8.385
3 Industrials Methanol 0.017** −0.121 0.176 0.297 −3.621 −9.718 −6.097
4 Energy Coking coal 0.032** 0.289 0.401 0.112 −0.81 −8.503 −7.693
5 Agriculture Corn 0.112* 0.211 0.459 0.248 −8.000 −12.054 −4.054
  • Note: This table reports the economic gains for all the commodity futures with statistically significant out-of-sample performance. The R OS 2 is similarly obtained as R i , OS 2 = 1 MSFE i , model MSFE i , bench and the statistical significance is constructed following Clark and West (2007). We calculate the Shape ratio (SR) and certainty equivalent return (CER) for both models using supply-chain predictor and historical average return during out-of-sample evaluation period as follows (1) risky asset weights calculation: w i , t = ( 1 γ ) R ˆ i , t + 1 σ ˆ i , t + 1 ; (2) portfolio allocation: R i , port , t + 1 = w i , t R i , t + 1 + R f , t + 1 ; (3) annualized economic measures construction: SR i , port = H μ ˆ i , port σ ˆ i , po rt and CER i , port = H ( μ ˆ i , port 1 2 γ σ ˆ i, port 2 ). *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan. 2005–Dec. 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period. The initial in-sample period covers two years (500 daily observations).

Similarly, Panel B of Table 9 reports the results for the allocated portfolio including customer-side equities and the risk-free asset. For all five commodity futures with significantly positive R OS 2 s, the Sharpe ratio gains are all positive while only glass and iron ore, which have the highest R OS 2 s, obtain positive CER gains. Moreover, most other commodity futures with insignificant out-of-sample R OS 2 s exhibit even worse Sharpe ratio gains and CER gains.

Based on our portfolio allocation exercise, we find that the magnitude of R OS 2 should, at a minimum, exceed approximately 0.10% to obtain economic significance. We confirm that commodity futures with strong in-sample and out-of-sample predictive significance can obtain economic gains from the perspective of the Sharpe ratio and CER. Additionally, the statistical and economic significance of the out-of-sample forecasting tests among several typical commodities continue to suggest that commodity futures returns substantially and positively affect the supplier-side equity returns and customer-side equity returns on the next trading day.

5 EXTENSIVE ANALYSIS

5.1 Predictability over business cycle

Previous studies (e.g., Cochrane, 2008; Fama & French, 1989) document that the predictable component of equity returns should be closely related to the business cycle. Using the data from the FRED database, we construct the OECD dated business cyclical recessions and expansions for China and thereby differentiate the out-of-sample evaluation period using business cycle. To analyze the role of commodity futures returns when predicting equity stock returns over the business cycle, we define
R OS , i , c 2 = 1 t = d + 1 T I t c ( R i , t R ˆ i , t ) 2 t = d + 1 T I t c ( R i , t R ¯ i , t ) 2 , for c = EXP , REC , (14)
where I t EXP I t REC is a dummy indicator variable that takes the value of one when day t is an OECD dated expansion (recession) and zero otherwise.

In Table 10, we report the out-of-sample forecasting results over the business cycle. On the supplier side, of the 36 commodity futures, the R OS , i , REC 2 s for 27 futures are higher during the recession period than there are during the expansion period. We also find that 16 commodity futures during the recession period exhibit significantly positive R OS , i , REC 2 values that exceed the number during the full sample period. Further, the respective magnitudes of R OS , i , REC 2 for iron ore, glass and coking coal are 1.451%, 1.209%, and 1.117% during the recession period and this indicates that relatively substantial economic significance is obtained for the three commodities. The average R OS , i 2 also increases from −0.062% during the full sample period to 0.056% during the recession period. On the customer side, as presented in the last four columns of Table 10, a similar result for the predictability over business cycle is obtained. The results above are consistent with the previously confirmed hypothesis that economic recessions would increase the investors' risk aversion and thus enhance their demands for higher risk premiums, which drive stronger return predictability in the stock market.

Table 10. Out-of-sample performance around business cycles
Supplier Customer
Recession Expansion Recession Expansion
Futures category Futures name R OS 2 ( % ) CW R OS 2 ( % ) CW R OS 2 ( % ) CW R OS 2 ( % ) CW
Metals Silver 0.234 1.15 0.042 0.71 −0.063 0.06 0.141 1.08
Metals Aluminum −0.164 −0.01 0.013 0.55 −0.081 −0.54 −0.003 0.49
Metals Gold −0.068 −0.90 0.045 0.82 −0.199 −0.82 0.079 0.96
Metals Copper 0.123 1.08 −0.104 0.11 −0.128 −0.76 −0.011 0.35
Metals Iron ore 1.451** 2.13 −0.334 1.19 1.103** 2.09 −0.258 1.17
Metals Nickel 0.740* 1.43 0.138 0.80 0.047 0.97 −0.199 0.76
Metals Lead −0.069 0.14 0.239 1.23 −0.220 −2.12 −0.045 −0.77
Metals Steel rebar 0.431** 1.82 −0.307 1.27 0.021 0.73 −0.269 0.47
Metals Silicon manganese 0.022 0.37 −0.272 −0.55 0.131 0.92 −0.112 −0.56
Metals Tin −0.042 0.82 −0.926 0.16 0.712 1.05 −1.158 −0.15
Metals Zinc 0.296* 1.58 −0.278* 1.52 −0.041 −1.25 −0.088 −1.96
Industrials Glass 1.209*** 3.19 −2.950 −0.49 1.103*** 2.90 −2.254 0.77
Industrials Hot rolled coil −6.653 0.60 −1.097 1.12 −7.298 −0.80 −2.225 −0.66
Industrials LLDPE 0.453** 1.95 −0.013 0.87 0.120* 1.56 −0.140 −1.25
Industrials Methanol 0.317* 1.51 −0.552* 1.34 0.521** 1.92 −1.756 0.16
Industrials PP 0.246** 1.92 −1.043 0.36 1.703** 2.31 −1.889 −1.54
Industrials Natural rubber 0.817*** 2.40 0.358** 1.81 0.040 0.65 −0.107 −0.36
Industrials PTA 0.127* 1.57 −0.148 0.00 0.007 0.29 −0.203 −1.01
Industrials PVC 0.104 1.21 −0.638 −1.44 0.201* 1.63 −0.793 −0.91
Energy Bitumen 0.930** 1.88 −1.721 0.22 −0.004** 2.06 −2.698 1.21
Energy Coke 0.379** 2.06 −1.062 0.71 0.262** 1.78 −0.852 0.21
Energy Coking coal 1.117*** 2.67 −2.177 1.09 0.701** 2.23 −1.387 0.57
Energy Thermal coal 0.144 1.09 0.470** 1.88 −0.100 0.77 −0.020* 1.43
Agriculture No. 1 soybean −0.036 0.59 −0.089 0.15 −0.158 −0.34 −0.093 −0.47
Agriculture No. 2 soybean −0.085 −0.12 −0.167 −0.88 −0.113 −1.61 −0.221 −1.81
Agriculture Corn 0.275** 1.79 −0.294 −0.36 0.404*** 2.43 −0.379 −0.97
Agriculture Cotton −0.078 −0.19 −0.043 0.22 −0.016 0.11 −0.291 −0.57
Agriculture Corn starch 0.278*** 2.35 −0.148 −0.63 0.423** 1.89 −0.321 −0.86
Agriculture Egg −0.255 −2.02 −0.079 −0.75 −0.229 −2.26 −0.123 −1.23
Agriculture Soybean meal −0.132 0.04 −0.146 −0.04 −0.098 0.18 −0.151 −0.23
Agriculture Rapeseed oil 0.015 0.46 −0.111 −0.87 0.021 0.82 −0.061 −1.37
Agriculture Palm oil 0.038 0.72 −0.043 −0.31 0.110 1.22 −0.117 −0.91
Agriculture Rapeseed meal −0.399 −0.97 −0.073 0.16 −0.343 −1.80 −0.033 −0.19
Agriculture White sugar 0.126 1.00 −0.170 0.14 −0.158 −1.40 0.036 0.69
Agriculture Wheat WH 0.236** 1.81 −0.363 0.45 0.111 1.25 −0.260 0.19
Agriculture Soybean oil −0.094 0.27 0.041 0.77 −0.073 −0.25 −0.104 −1.05
0.056 −0.389 −0.044 −0.510
  • Note: This table reports the out-of-sample forecasting performance around business cycle for both supplier side and customer side. The forecasts R ˆ i , t + 1 is obtained from R ˆ i , t + 1 = α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t and historical average return R ˆ i , t + 1 HA = R ̅ i , t + 1 = ( 1 / t ) d = 1 t R i , d is used as benchmark model. We construct the OECD dated business cyclical recessions and expansions for China and thus separate the out-of-sample period using business cycle. R OS , i , c 2 is to analyze the role of commodity futures returns for stock return prediction over business cycle, We calculate R OS , i , c 2 = 1 t = d + 1 T I t c R i , t R ˆ i , t 2 t = d + 1 T I t c ( R i , t R ̅ i , t ) 2 , for c = EXP , REC, where I t EXP and I t REC is a dummy indicator variable that takes the value of one when day t is a OECD dated expansion (recession) and zero otherwise. The statistical significance of R OS 2 is constructed following Clark and West (2007). *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan. 2005–Dec. 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period. The initial in-sample period covers two years (500 daily observations).

5.2 Forecasting results with economic constraints

It is important to understand the influence of imposing sensible restrictions on the out-of-sample prediction exercise given that the direct use of an unrestricted out-of-sample forecasting strategy varies slightly from the realistic economic constraints. In practice, investors always impose prior knowledge of the output of the predictive model. They may not use a negative forecast of the equity premium but rather simply conclude that such an estimate is zero. According to Campbell and Thompson (2008), we add a restriction for the distribution of predictive excess returns by limiting R ˆ i , t + 1 to be above zero and we would not invest in the portfolio when the predictive excess returns are negative. Accordingly, the truncated forecasts in Equation (15) provide the form of the predictive equity premium with this nonnegative constraint:
R ˆ i , t + 1 = max ( 0 , α ˆ i , t + β ˆ i , t R _ com i , t ) . (15)
Second, the equity premium constraint does not take the time-varying coefficient estimates ( α ˆ i , t and β ˆ i , t ) into consideration but rather just operates using the forecasts. Here, we follow Pettenuzzo et al. (2014) and use the annualized conditional Sharpe ratio constraint specified in Equation (16). The Sharpe ratio is conditionally dependent on both the first and second moments of the return distribution, and thus, we can build multiple-dimensional constraints for the forecasts. Thus, we set the Sharpe ratio bounds as follows:
SR l H α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t σ ˆ i , t + 1 SR h . (16)

When SR l = 0, it is the same as imposing the return premium constraint. When SR h = 1, it corresponds to almost the inaccessible limit of a non-leveraged stock portfolio. Moreover, σ ˆ i , t + 1 is estimated from the GARCH (1,1) model using the daily observations in the previous 6 months. H = 250 is the number of trading days in 1 year. Similarly, if the new forecast does not satisfy the Sharpe ratio bounds, we make zero investment. Tables 11 and 12 report the out-of-sample R OS 2 s considering the economic constraints on the supplier-side and customer-side, respectively. R OS 2 , which measures the difference in the R OS 2 s of the unrestricted model and restricted model, is also reported.

Table 11. Out-of-sample performance considering economic constraints: Supplier-side
No. Futures category Futures name Supplier
Equity premium constraint Sharpe ratio constraint
R OS 2 ( % ) CW R OS 2 ( % ) R OS 2 ( % ) CW R OS 2 ( % )
1 Metals Silver 0.374** 2.30 0.185 0.190*** 3.15 0.001
2 Metals Aluminum 0.027 0.86 0.110 0.168** 1.89 0.251
3 Metals Gold 0.073** 2.00 0.100 0.069** 1.97 0.096
4 Metals Copper 0.098* 1.38 0.079 0.104* 1.63 0.085
5 Metals Iron ore 0.179* 1.42 −0.455 0.201* 1.41 −0.433
6 Metals Nickel 0.217* 1.35 −0.060 0.035 0.51 −0.242
7 Metals Lead 0.219* 1.53 0.210 0.133** 1.98 0.124
8 Metals Steel rebar 0.027* 1.35 −0.179 0.107** 1.84 −0.099
9 Metals Silicon manganese −0.254 −0.84 −0.037 0.123 1.08 0.340
10 Metals Tin −0.085 0.91 0.577 0.138** 1.92 0.800
11 Metals Zinc 0.088** 1.85 0.066 0.069* 1.32 0.047
12 Industrials Glass 0.179** 2.17 −0.112 0.158 1.12 −0.133
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil −2.318 −0.15 0.147 0.392** 1.88 2.857
14 Industrials LLDPE 0.250*** 2.63 −0.008 0.145** 2.10 −0.113
15 Industrials Methanol 0.337*** 2.55 0.211 0.023 0.70 −0.103
16 Industrials PP −0.298* 1.38 0.443 −0.026 0.35 0.715
17 Industrials Natural rubber 0.308** 2.00 −0.323 0.180*** 2.62 −0.451
18 Industrials PTA 0.039 0.85 0.038 0.065 1.05 0.064
19 Industrials PVC 0.037 1.25 0.119 −0.004 0.25 0.078
20 Energy Bitumen −0.647 0.56 −0.328 0.447** 2.15 0.766
21 Energy Coke −0.054** 1.69 −0.041 0.140** 1.75 0.153
22 Energy Coking coal −0.104** 1.88 −0.324 0.120* 1.39 −0.100
23 Energy Thermal coal 0.395** 1.91 0.086 0.268** 2.21 −0.041
24 Agriculture No. 1 soybean 0.022 0.70 0.078 0.032* 1.50 0.088
25 Agriculture No. 2 soybean −0.090 −0.38 0.026 0.056* 1.60 0.172
26 Agriculture Corn 0.069* 1.32 0.005 0.020* 1.40 −0.044
27 Agriculture Cotton −0.045 0.02 0.019 −0.028 1.12 0.036
28 Agriculture Corn starch 0.034 0.63 0.009 0.130** 1.71 0.105
29 Agriculture Egg −0.167 −2.06 0.000 0.173* 1.36 0.340
30 Agriculture Soybean meal −0.093 0.07 0.044 0.033 1.18 0.170
31 Agriculture Rapeseed oil −0.031 −0.33 0.006 0.101* 1.44 0.138
32 Agriculture Palm oil 0.060* 1.58 0.051 0.059* 1.59 0.050
33 Agriculture Rapeseed meal −0.212 −0.61 0.110 0.263* 1.36 0.585
34 Agriculture White sugar −0.023 0.74 −0.047 0.515*** 3.06 0.491
35 Agriculture Wheat WH 0.060* 1.63 0.053 0.054* 1.45 0.047
36 Agriculture Soybean oil −0.096 −0.13 −0.044 0.423*** 3.03 0.475
Avg. −0.040 0.023 0.141 0.203
  • Note: This table reports the out-of-sample forecasting performance with economic constraints on the supplier side, individually with equity premium constraint and Sharpe ratio constraint. The forecasts R ˆ i , t + 1 is obtained from R ˆ i , t + 1 = α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t and historical average return R ˆ i , t + 1 HA = R ̅ i , t + 1 = ( 1 / t ) d = 1 t R i , d is used as benchmark model. We set α ˆ i , t + β ˆ i , t R com i , t 0 as return premium constraint and 0 H α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t σ i , t + 1 1 as Sharpe ratio constraint for our univariate forecasting model. The R OS 2 is similarly obtained as R i , OS 2 = 1 MSFE i , model MSFE i , bench and the statistical significance is constructed following Clark and West (2007). R OS 2 measures the difference of R OS 2 in the unrestricted model and restricted model. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan. 2005–Dec. 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period. The initial in-sample period covers two years (500 daily observations).
Table 12. Out-of-sample performance considering economic constraints: customer-side
Customer
Equity premium constraint Sharpe ratio constraint
No. Futures category Futures name R OS 2 ( % ) CW R OS 2 ( % ) R OS 2 ( % ) CW R OS 2 ( % )
1 Metals Silver 0.042 0.73 0.064 0.143 1.03 0.165
2 Metals Aluminum −0.036 0.00 0.014 0.123** 1.89 0.173
3 Metals Gold 0.056 1.14 0.159 −0.027 −0.11 0.076
4 Metals Copper −0.056 −0.09 0.025 0.097** 1.82 0.178
5 Metals Iron ore 0.052* 1.43 −0.308 0.451** 2.19 0.091
6 Metals Nickel −0.587 −0.03 −0.430 −0.099 −0.32 0.058
7 Metals Lead 0.007 0.47 0.192 0.081* 1.44 0.266
8 Metals Steel rebar −0.002 0.88 0.049 0.023 0.60 0.074
9 Metals Silicon manganese −0.076 −0.37 0.001 0.266* 1.63 0.343
10 Metals Tin −0.362 0.35 0.403 0.113* 1.53 0.878
11 Metals Zinc −0.049 −2.10 0.012 −0.040 −0.72 0.021
12 Industrials Glass 0.167** 2.19 −0.280 0.210 1.22 −0.237
13 Industrials Hot rolled coil −3.279 −1.42 0.847 0.681*** 2.78 4.807
14 Industrials LLDPE 0.093** 2.07 0.094 −0.026 −0.26 −0.025
15 Industrials Methanol 0.317*** 2.54 0.300 0.141** 1.93 0.124
16 Industrials PP −0.082 1.18 0.362 0.170* 1.44 0.614
17 Industrials Natural rubber −0.013 0.42 0.005 0.049* 1.33 0.067
18 Industrials PTA −0.065 −0.50 0.008 0.232*** 2.39 0.305
19 Industrials PVC 0.091** 1.70 0.140 0.097* 1.38 0.146
20 Energy Bitumen −1.524 0.81 −0.371 0.903*** 2.73 2.056
21 Energy Coke 0.050** 1.84 0.122 0.095** 1.68 0.167
22 Energy Coking coal −0.027** 1.65 −0.059 0.280* 1.41 0.248
23 Energy Thermal coal 0.108 1.24 0.177 0.234* 1.34 0.303
24 Agriculture No. 1 soybean −0.127 −0.60 0.007 0.044 1.23 0.178
25 Agriculture No. 2 soybean −0.115 −2.19 0.038 0.065 1.27 0.218
26 Agriculture Corn 0.091* 1.43 −0.021 0.138** 1.91 0.026
27 Agriculture Cotton −0.076 −0.29 0.043 0.009 1.12 0.128
28 Agriculture Corn starch 0.058 0.81 0.044 0.096 0.79 0.082
29 Agriculture Egg −0.179 −2.53 0.002 0.804*** 2.56 0.985
30 Agriculture Soybean meal −0.109 −0.08 0.009 0.074* 1.50 0.192
31 Agriculture Rapeseed oil −0.012 −0.33 0.003 0.116* 1.54 0.131
32 Agriculture Palm oil 0.030 0.84 0.000 0.212*** 2.41 0.182
33 Agriculture Rapeseed meal −0.199 −1.47 0.082 −0.058 0.06 0.223
34 Agriculture White sugar −0.092 −0.52 0.005 0.408*** 2.95 0.505
35 Agriculture Wheat WH −0.009 0.96 0.027 0.054* 1.55 0.090
36 Agriculture Soybean oil −0.051 −0.28 0.034 0.217** 2.27 0.302
Avg. −0.166 0.050 0.177 0.393
  • Note: This table reports the out-of-sample forecasting performance with economic constraints on the customer side, individually with equity premium constraint and Sharpe ratio constraint. The forecasts R ˆ i , t + 1 is obtained from R ˆ i , t + 1 = α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t and historical average return R ˆ i , t + 1 HA = R ̅ i , t + 1 = ( 1 / t ) d = 1 t R i , d is used as benchmark model. We set α ˆ i , t + β ˆ i , t R com i , t 0 as return premium constraint and 0 H α ˆ i , t + 1 + β ˆ i , t + 1 R _ com i , t σ i , t + 1 1 as Sharpe ratio constraint for our univariate forecasting model. The R OS 2 is similarly obtained as R i , OS 2 = 1 MSFE i , model MSFE i , bench and the statistical significance is constructed following Clark and West (2007). R OS 2 measures the difference of R OS 2 in the unrestricted model and restricted model. *, **, and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively. The full sample period covers Jan. 2005–Dec. 2019 and the number of trading days for each commodity varies within the full sample period. The initial in-sample period covers two years (500 daily observations).

With respect to the supplier-side out-of-sample predictability, Tables 11 shows that the average R OS , i 2 can increase from −0.062% in the unrestricted model to −0.040% if the equity premium constraint is imposed or increase to 0.141% if the Sharpe ratio constraint is imposed. Moreover, among the 36 commodity futures, 23 commodities exhibit higher R OS , i 2 s under the equity premium constraint, and 26 commodities exhibit higher R OS , i 2 s under the Sharpe ratio constraint. Finally, the Sharpe ratio constraint substantially improves the significance of the following commodity returns as predictors for supplier-side equity returns: 9 out of 11 metal futures (i.e., silver, aluminum, gold, copper, iron ore, lead, steel rebar, steel rebar, tin, and zinc), 3 out of 8 industrial futures (i.e., hot rolled oil, LLDPE, and natural rubber), all the energy futures (i.e., bitumen, coke, coking coal, and thermal coal) and 11 out of 13 agriculture futures (i.e., No. 1 soybeans, No. 2 soybeans, corn, corn starch, eggs, rapeseed oil, palm oil, rapeseed meal, white sugar, wheat WH, and soybean oil).

The customer-side results presented in Table 12 indicate a more significant out-of-sample performance improvement, especially under the Sharpe ratio constraint with an average 0.177% of R OS , i 2 . The average enhancement of the R OS , i 2 under the Sharpe ratio constraint is 0.393% here, which is larger than the enhancement of 0.203% on the supplier side. Furthermore, the most predominant result is that all the energy futures returns can predict customer-side equity returns under the Sharpe ratio constraint while the performances for other categories are also significantly improved. Therefore, considering the realistic constraints in the out-of-sample forecasting, we further confirm such cross-market supply-chain return predictability for most of the reported commodity futures.

6 CONCLUSION

In this paper, we examine the supply-chain equity return predictability using commodity futures returns in China's financial market. Our study enriches two strands of literature: the asset price linkage across different markets and the stock return predictability using supply-chain information. We find that the cross-market information and supply-chain information are valuable for stock return predictability in China's financial market, which is the world's largest commodity futures market and the second-largest equity market.

In the in-sample analysis, we find that a considerable number of commodity futures exhibit predictive power for the equity returns, especially for supplier-side equity returns. We identify the overall macroeconomic risk premium, which is captured by the common factor from all commodity futures returns, as an important source of this predictability.

In the out-of-sample analysis, we find this supply-chain predictive ability weakens but still exists. More important, both in-sample and out-of-sample tests indicate that there is asymmetric predictability between the supplier side and customer side. This may be due to that commodity prices positively contribute to the revenue of supplier-side firms, or the stock prices of more concentrated supplier-side firms become more sensitive to the shock of commodity prices. Finally, we find that the predictability of such cross-market supply-chain information is more prominent during recessionary business periods, or with economic constraints.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

The authors thank helpful comments from an anonymous referee, and Bob Webb (the editor). This study is supported by National Natural Science Foundation of China under Grants 71790592 and 71771144.

    DATA AVAILABILITY STATEMENT

    The information for the data sets that support our study is obtained from several sources: (a) China's A-share stock trading data, commodity futures trading data, and risk-free rate are obtained from the database of Chinese Stock Market & Accounting Research (CSMAR). (b) The cross-market supply-chain linkage between commodities and equities are from the Wind database; however, restrictions apply to the availability of the first two sets of data, which were used under license for this study. (c) The Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) dated recession indicators for China are from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), and are available at https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/CHNRECDM.

    • 1 The Wind company is known as “the market leader in China's financial information services industry,” and its access information can be found in our Data Availability Statement.
    • 2 We thank the anonymous referee for pointing out this potential explanation for the asymmetric predictability.

    The full text of this article hosted at iucr.org is unavailable due to technical difficulties.